The words you are searching are inside this book. To get more targeted content, please make full-text search by clicking here.

017_The_Economic_DEVELOPMENT_(book4you.org)_165

Discover the best professional documents and content resources in AnyFlip Document Base.
Search
Published by soedito, 2018-06-06 22:45:37

017_The_Economic_DEVELOPMENT_(book4you.org)_165

017_The_Economic_DEVELOPMENT_(book4you.org)_165

Turning Back to the Market 239

decline in the demographic dependency ratio) that coincided with the reform
period buoyed per capita GDP growth.

The countries shown above the diagonal line are the ones whose labor product-
ivity increased more rapidly during the reform period than during the phase of
state-led industrialization. Those in which it grew more slowly during the latter
period appear below the diagonal line. As the reader can appreciate, the first group
is composed solely of Chile and the Dominican Republic (the two strongest
economies of the last two decades) and Uruguay, which grew slowly during
both of these periods. Argentina is close to the diagonal line, but is in a situation
more similar to that of Uruguay, in that its labor-productivity gains were not very
substantial in either period. The other countries (fourteen in total) had slower
growth rates during the reform period than during the phase of state-led indus·
trialization. The countries in the worst position within this group include the
region's two largest economies (Brazil and Mexico), along with Ecuador, Para-
guay, and Venezuela, as well as Bolivia, Colombia, and Honduras.

Various studies on trends in total factor productivity corroborate these find-
ings. Although they use different methodologies, these studies indicate that total
factor productivity has grown more slowly or has actually declined since 1990,
whereas it increased sharply during the period of state-led industrialization (IDB
2010; Aravena et al. 2010; Palma 2011). Figure 4.6 (see Chapter 4) provides an
overview of the estimates presented in a recent IDB study (2010). After climbing
until the mid-1970s, total productivity fell sharply during the debt crisis, and its
growth was sluggish or even slightly negative between 1990 and 2005 (the last year
for which the study provides estimates). The widening productivity gap between
the region and the United States is accounted for entirely by the trend since 1980,
and this gap continued to grow during the period of market reforms. The country
data provided in this study shows that Chile and the Dominican Republic were the
only countries to register significant productivity gains in 1990-2005, which were
even greater than those experienced in 1960-74.

The reasons for this poor performance in terms of productivity growth have
been extensively debated. The first point that should be brought out in this respect
is that these aggregate indicators reflect the marked asymmetries that exist
between the productivity gains achieved by successful firms and sectors, on the
one hand, and the increasing under-utilization of production resources, particu-
larly labor, on the other. Productivity did rise in strong firms and sectors (agri-
business, mining, and modern telecommunications, financial and transport
services). This tren~ was no doubt supported by growing integration into the
world economy, FDI, the emergence of the trans-Latins, and privatizations. At the
same time, however, the informal labor market was also expanding, which drove
down the productivity of the services sectors, where informal workers seek refuge.
As a result, today there are more world-class firms present in the region, many of
which are transnationals (or trans-Latins), but there are also a growing number of
low-productivity small businesses and microenterprises. In other words, the
region's internal dualism (structural heterogeneity, to use the term traditionally
employed by ECLAC) has increased. The idea that an increase in productivity in
internationalized sectors would spread out to the rest of the economy and would
boost economic growth has therefore not been borne out; in fact, relative levels of

240 Economic Development of Latin America

productivity of different sectors and firms within each economy tended to become
more unequal.

The path taken by the liberalization process no doubt contributed to this
outcome during the years when the reform effort was at its height. The prevailing
trend at the microeconomic level was for firms to adopt "defensive" strategies for
adapting to the new situation that focused on low-cost organizational, production,
and marketing restructuring, rather than "offensive" ones, which would have
involved combining these processes with substantial new investments in equip-
ment and technologies, as well as strategic alliances. As a result, the Schumpeter-
ian process of "creative destruction" that took place at that time appears to have
involved more destruction than creation, since the labor, capital, technological
capabilities, and, at times, land that were displaced from the sectors and firms in
which production processes were restructured were not properly absorbed by the
sectors that were expanding. The increasing integration of the world economy
made it easier to import intermediate products and equipment. This helped many
firms to boost their productivity, but at the cost of the destruction of existing
production chains. As a consequence of the predominance of defensive restruc-
turings, the average investment rate remained low during the 1990-7 expansion
and did not bounce back until the boom of2004-8, although, as we saw, even then
it remained below its 1975-80 peak (see Table 5.1).

The restructuring of production sectors was also marked by a premature
de-industrialization process entailing a reduction in the share of manufacturing
production in the economy and job creation at lower levels of per capita GDP than
those registered when de-industrialization has taken place in industrialized coun-
tries (Palma 2005). In the preceding chapter, Figure 4.4 illustrates how strong this
trend was, both during the lost decade and in the two decades that followed, while
Table 5.8 shows that industrial output stagnated during the lost decade (as the
aggregate effect of increases in some countries and decreases in others) and then
grew very slowly during the next two decades (as may be seen from a comparison
of the figures set out in Table 4.6). The best-performing industrial sectors included
the maquila industry, some natural-resource processing industries, the automo-
tive sector (which, in Mexico, was aided by that country's access to the US market
and, in South America, was promoted by special protection measures put in place
in the context of the subregional integration processes), and branches of industry
that catered to the local market during periods of booming domestic demand (e.g.,
construction materials, beverages, and food processing). The industries that were
hurt the most were more traditional, labor-intensive activities (apparel, footwear,
leather manufactures, furniture, etc.), except for maquila-related industries.

The region's manufacturing sectors also lagged behind the global technological
frontier, and this was true not only of labor-intensive and engineering-intensive
sectors but also of natural-resource-intensive industries, as is shown up by
comparisons of productivity levels in Latin America and the United States.
Moreover, this was occurring in a situation marked by a very low level of capacity
to generate new technologies, not only in comparison with the more diversified
industrialized and dynamic Asian economies, but also with the more developed
natural-resource-intensive economies. This was reflected in a lower share of
engineering-intensive industries, a very scant degree of research and development,
and a near absence of patenting of technological innovations in relation to all

Turning Back to the Market 241

Table 5.8. Dynamics of productive sectors (annual growth rates)

Agriculture Manufacturing Dynamic services•

1980-1990 1990-2008 1980-1990 1990-2008 1980-1990 1990-2008

Argentina 1.3 2.8 -2.1 3.3 0.0 5.1

Bolivia 1.7 3.0 -0.7 3.8 0.6 4.7

Brazil 2.5 3.8 -0.2 2.2 3.7 3.0

Chile 6.0 5.0 2.6 3.9 2.5 6.1

Colombia 3.0 2.2 2.9 2.2 3.5 4.2

Costa Rica 3.1 3.7 2.2 5.3 4.1 6.8

Cuba -2.3 0.3 2.2

Ecuador 4.2 4.4 3.0 0.4 2.9 4.2

El Salvador -1.4 2.3 -0.9 4.1 3.5

Guatemala 1.3 2.9 -0.1 2.7 2.6 6.4

Honduras 2.7 3.1 3.0 4.5 5.1 7.2

Mexico 1.2 2.0 2.0 2.9 3.4 4.3

Nicaragua -0.7 3.7 -2.8 4.2 -1.2 4.3

Panama 2.9 3.8 0.7 1.9 2.1 6.7

Paraguay 4.0 4.3 2.2 l.l 4.3 3.5

Peru 2.2 4.6 -1.9 4.8 0.6 5.2

Dominican Republic 0.4 2.7 2.1 4.9 4.5 7.0

Uruguay -0.2 2.9 -1.0 2.0 2.8 3.2

Venezuela 2.0 2.5 1.9 1.9 2.3 3.8

Latin America 2.3 2.9 0.1 2.7 3.1 4.1

)!Transport, communications, and financial services
Source: ECLAC historical series at 1990 and 2000 constant prices, respectively

these groups of economies (ECLAC 2007a; Cimoli and Porcile 2011). The slug-
gishness of the countries' national innovation systems that had been a feature of
the preceding stage of development thus remained in evidence, and the situation
actually deteriorated somewhat further.

Agriculture withstood the events of the lost decade better than other sectors,
but its growth rate both then and in the following years has been lower than it
typically was before the debt crisis: 2.9 percent in 1990-2008 vs 3.5 percent in
1950-74. Thus, the elimination of the previous trade regime's so-called "anti-
agricultural bias" did not have the positive effects that market-reform advocates
had expected, even in cases (as occurred in a number of countries) where the
substantial reduction or outright elimination of measures that discriminated
against agro-exporting sectors was coupled with increased protection for agricul-
tural producers that were competing with imports (Anderson and Valdes 2008).
Thus, the reduction in internal technological, financial, and marketing support
mechanisms for the agricultural sector, as part of the restructuring of the state
apparatus that took place during the reform process, in many (or even most) cases
outweighed the advantages of doing away with the trade bias against that sector.
In addition, as had also occurred during the previous development phase, the
periodic appreciation of the exchange rate worked to the disadvantage of the

agricultural sector.
This aggregate trend in agricultural production is a composite of widely varying

experiences, however. Agriculture has grown more robustly in Bolivia, Chile,
Paraguay, Peru, and Uruguay in recent decades that it did during the period of

242 Economic Development of Latin America

state-led industrialization, but just the opposite is true of Colombia, Guatemala,
Mexico, Nicaragua, and Venezuela, while the sector's growth rates were quite
similar in these two periods in Brazil (compare, in this regard, the figures given in
Table 5.8 and those shown in Table 4.6). What is more, some of the most dynamic
agricultural activities followed long-term trends that were unaffected by reforms,
with the most outstanding examples being the strong performance of soybean
crops in a number of South American economies and poultry production in a
broader range of countries.

Overall, the most robust sectors were modern services (i.e., public utilities,
transport, and financial and business services) (see Table 5.8). These industries
continued to grow during the debt crisis and have been the strongest since 1990.
Their combined share of Latin America's GDP has increased by nearly 8 percent-
age points since 1980. A notable change in these sectors relative to the situation
during the period of state-led industrialization is that they are now populated by
more private enterprises, including, in many cases, transnational corporations.
Generally speaking, the mining sector also grew more rapidly in resource-rich
countries, but extractive activities have expanded more rapidly than the process-
ing of minerals that generate more value-added. As in the case of modern services,
mining activities have received a boost from institutional reforms designed to
open up more areas to the private sector and FDI. In the case of both mineral
resources and intellectual property, one of the thrusts of the reform process has
been to provide greater protection to property rights.

The strength of the export sector does not appear to have helped to speed the
economy's overall growth. As pointed out by ECLAC (2001a) and, more recently,
by Palma (2009 and 2011), the region's share in world markets has been increas-
ing in export sectors in which international markets are not dynamic, in sharp
contrast with the patterns seen in East Asia. Hausmann (2011) also notes that the
activities in which Latin America has specialized offer fewer opportunities for
setting up new production activities or for making improvements in product
quality-two areas of progress that are considered to be essential for rapid
economic growth. To use Hausmann's terminology, the region has tended to
specialize in a portion of the "product space" that offers fewer opportunities for
technological change.

As noted in the preceding section, many of the more successful export sectors,
especially manufacturing, tend to employ a large number of imported compon-
ents and, in the extreme case of the maquila industry, generate very little domestic
value-added. This means that there may be a significant difference between the
growth registered for exports of manufactures, which is measured as gross value,
and the manufacturing sector's GDP (i.e., the value-added). In fact, as demon-
strated by Akyiiz (2003: ch. I, especially table 1.5), the increase in Latin America's
share of world trade in manufactures experienced during the closing decades of
the twentieth century coincided with a reduction in its share of the global
manufacturing sector's value-added. This is also illustrated by World Bank statis-
tics, which show that Latin America's share of world manufacturing value-added
fell from 7.2 percent in 1980 to 6.2 percent in 2007 and that the decrease was even
sharper relative to the performance of developing countries as a whole (i.e.,
excluding the high-income OECD countries), where the region's share slid from

Turning Back to the Market 243

..t:: ~6;0%.~----------------------------------~~~~-=--­

~ Panama Dominican Republic

••

Chile

Ql ---5~o.--l-----------------------------------~•--8e+w----vOr-S=la R'ICa

.~

: --4;0"1<:,-+--------------------------- temala

c +• Honduras

(!) Colombia

(ij Uru~uay• Ecuador + El Salvador
:I •- - - - - - - - - - : o 7 " " : : : : : _ _ __ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _ _18:>:r~a:;;zi~llN i c a r a g u a -
1: Paraguay

<1:
---{3;09/c

• • Mexico

0 1.0% 3.0% 5.0% 7.0% 9.0%

-1.0%

Annual growth rate of exports

Figure 5.11. Relationship between export and GDP growth, 1990-2010

31.2 percent to 18.0 percent in the same period. 19 This trend is particularly clear
in the case of Mexico, where the surge in exports of manufactures since 1980 and,
in particular, since the signing of NAFTA, coincided with a slack growth rate in
manufacturing GDP (value-added): 3.0 percent in 1994-2008, according to the
ECLAC data that were used to draw up Table 5.8 and only slightly over 2.2 percent
in 1980-94, versus the 8.0 percent rate shown in Table 4.6 for 1950-74.

The way in which these factors were combined in different countries varied a
great deal, which helps to account for the low correlation that exists between GDP
growth and export growth in the countries of the region for 1990-2010 (see
Figure 5.11). The rapid growth of Mexico's export sector, for example, translated
into a far slower GDP growth rate than in Costa Rica and Chile or than in Peru
and the Dominican Republic. This appears to demonstrate that the combination
of limited domestic production linkages and the destructive effects of liberaliza-
tion (e.g., the destruction of pre-existing production chains) had a strong impact
in Mexico, whereas the development of new export industries in Costa Rica
underpinned a marked net creation of production capacity, while, in Chile, the
destructive effects of liberalization were felt earlier on, in the 1970s. The destruc-
tion of production capacity that occurred when the region's economies were
opened up to imports appears to have been greater in the larger countries,
which may be part of the explanation for the slower pace of growth experienced
by Brazil, Colombia, Mexico, and Venezuela relative to the regional average.

The fact that the Latin American economies have been relatively successful in
opening up their economies to the international market but have been growing

19 These estimates have been arrived at using the World Bank's global development indicators
database.

244 Economic Development of Latin America

slowly is one of the paradoxical effects of market reforms. This has, once again,
opened the way for the supporters of industrial policies or, more generally,
production-sector development policies. This issue is closely related to techno-
logical development in today's open economies. ECLAC stands out among
the various international institutions in having continued to focus on this issue
during the time that reformers were, as noted earlier, emphasizing that "the best
industrial policy is no industrial policy" (see ECLAC 1990, 2000, and 2008).

Since the 1990s, progress has been made in some horizontal (i.e., non-
selective) policies, such as free-trade zones, support for microenterprises and
small and medium-sized businesses, ICT diffusion, and the design of techno-
logical funds. In addition, support has been provided for some production
chains and local production clusters. All of these policies are part of a strategy
to boost "competitiveness" (a term that does not carry with it all the negative
connotations associated with the concept of "industrial policy") and are
focused primarily on providing support for existing branches of activity rather
than diversifying the production base. In addition, some of the old sectoral
policies have remained in place, such as those that provide support for the
automotive industry in some South American countries and for the forestry
sector in others. In some cases, support for investment in individual firms
has played an important role, such as, for example, in the entry of INTEL in
Costa Rica, of mining enterprises in Peru, and of pulp and paper industries in
Uruguay (Peres 2012).

Starting at the turn of the century, there was a more widespread return to
sectoral policies in Argentina, Brazil, and Mexico and, later on, in Chile and
Colombia. Nevertheless, it was not until the 2008 launch of Brazil's production
development policy, and the simultaneous implementation in this country of a
policy focusing on building new production capacity around its oil discoveries,
that it can be said that there was a return to an ambitious industrial and, more
broadly, production sector development strategy. In the rest of the countries,
policies in this area remain limited, and the incentives they provide to businesses
are weak and complex, and are a far cry from those that protection measures and
other incentives provided during the previous phase of development.

The policy proposals for promoting the development of production that are
being put forward now tend to place more emphasis on science and technology,
an area that was largely neglected during the period of state-led industrialization.
The period of market reforms also introduced changes in the policies in this area.
In the 1990s, most of the countries began to move away from the supply-side
technology policies associated with the preceding stage of development and
toward a model focusing on demands from the production sector. The main
"horizontal" policy tools that were put in place-which were, at least in theory,
neutral in terms of their effect on the various production sectors-were the funds
made available to innovative investors, business counseling, and information
systems for innovative ventures, and quality control and certification mechan-
isms, especially for export products. Emphasis was also placed on the protection of
intellectual property as a means of attracting FDI, which was seen as a vehicle for
technical progress. Trade liberalization and the overvaluation of the exchange rate
in a number of the countries also paved the way for the introduction of technolo-
gies that were embedded in what had become cheaper capital goods.

Turning Back to the Market 245

These policies heightened the heterogeneity of the countries' production struc-
tures, since the design of co-financing arrangements had the effect of ensuring
that the main beneficiaries of these policies would be business ventures that
already had the capacity to innovate. At the Sj:lme time, the resources made
available for research and development remained very limited (0.54 percent of
GDP in 1998-2002, 0.57 percent in 2002-6 and 0.63 percent in 2007) (ECLAC
2010: table III.9). Brazil is the only Latin American country in which investment
in this area amounts to around 1 percent of GDP, and the majority of the
countries have investment rates in this area far below the regional average,
which is only a fraction (one fourth or one fifth) of the rate in countries that
invest heavily in technological development (Finland, the US, South Korea) and
half as much as the rate in China or Spain. Latin American investment in this area
comes largely from the government (over half), whereas the leading countries in
innovation rely more on the private sector. Latin America also lags even further
behind in terms of other indicators (number of scientists or of scientific publica-
tions per million of inhabitants, or the share of worldwide patenting) (ECLAC
2008: table III.l). 20

Meanwhile, at the same time that this dominant model was put in place, a
number of countries were making headway in developing more systemic
approaches to innovation. In the 1990s, Colombia and Costa Rica developed
more integrated innovation systems that were directed at ensuring that technol-
ogy supply and demand policies would be more closely interlinked and that there
would be broad sectoral and regional participation. In Colombia, efforts in this
area flagged in the late 1990s but were revived later on. In Argentina, Brazil, and
Mexico, progress was made in developing sectoral funds that played an important
role in enabling these countries to combine sectoral development policies with a
variety of instruments designed to identify demand components and to encourage
the private sector to invest in research and development. While Argentina and
Mexico focused more on demand, Brazil embraced a systemic model more similar
to the one used by Colombia and drew on a much larger pool of resources, as
mentioned earlier.

THE SOCIAL EFFECTS OF ECONOMIC TRANSFORMATIONS

The lost decade had a devastating effect on the region in terms of poverty levels.
For Latin America as a whole, the poverty rate climbed from 40.5 percent to 48.3
percent, with the rate in urban areas jumping by nearly 12 percentage points and
the already high rate in rural areas rising further (see Figure 5.12). The main cause
of this was the decline in the real income of workers and the steep decrease in
formal employment triggered by the deep recession, and the inflation that went
along with it. Income distribution also took a turn for the worse, with most of this

°2 For a more extensive discussion of this subject, see ECLAC (2008: chs III and IV) and ECLAC

(2010: ch. III).

246 Economic Development of Latin America

70.0

65.0 ---------------!+r£7&----------- - - - - --~-~-----
60.0
:- - -- ;-- - -- : ---

55.0 1-----~u;;J-------- --- :---

50.0 1----- :---- - 1----- -- :--- 1------- :--

45.0 - - --- -------- --- :-----

40.0 ;- --- ,-- __ 1--
---

35.0 -- 1--- ----- ---- 1--- 1-- 1----------

30.0 1-- 1-- i- 1--- 1- 1--
1--
25.0 c- 1---- 1-- 1--- :----- 1----

20.0 f-- '-- '---,- '-- ~ ~ '--
1980
1990 1997 2002 2005 2008 2009

J111 Total Urban tsJ RuraiJ

Figure 5.12. Poverty incidence

Source: ECLAC

deterioration being concentrated in the most acute phase of the crisis (see
Table 5.9).

The fiscal adjustments made during the lost decade did involve cuts in public
social spending, but this category of expenditure was reduced less than total public
spending. The net decline in social spending, measured as a percentage of GDP
(and it should be borne in mind that per capita GDP also contracted during this
period), amounted to a decrease of 9 percent in per capita social spending in
1982-9 relative to its level at the start of that decade. Social security was the most
heavily protected item of social expenditure (Cominetti and Ruiz 1998). Here
again, however, this aggregate figure is the result of a wide range of outcomes,
from countries in which social spending continued to rise through the 1980s, to
ones in which it plummeted.21 Despite the cuts made in some cases, education,
health, and other social indicators continued to improve. Nonetheless, the public
systems for social service delivery were hard hit, and this led to a loss of human
capital and a deterioration in the quality of those services.

During the subsequent reform phase, different social indicators have followed
contrasting trends. The most positive development has been the steady rise in

21 On the b<)sis of the data provided by Cominetti and Ruiz (1998), Brazil, Colombia, Costa Rica,
Honduras, Panama, and Uruguay can be classified as falling into the first group, while Guatemala, El
Salvador, Nicaragua, Peru, the Dominican Republic, and Venezuela can be placed in the second. In the
rest of the countries, social spending initially fell and then began to recover.

Turning Back to the Market 247

Table 5.9. Income distribution in Latin America (Gini coefficient) 2008

1980 1986 1992 1998 2002 46.3
54.2
Argentina 39.8 42.7 45.0 50.2 53.3 51.8
58.3 51.9
Brazil 57.4 58.0 60.1 59.2 54.8 44.5
56.6 57.2
Chile 52.9 56.1 54.7 55.5 45.4 55.6
60.1 53.4
Paraguay 53.3 55.8 52.7 57.1 55.6 48.0
56.5 43.5
Uruguay 40.2 41.2 42.1 44.0 51.4 48.7
47.5 46.9
Bolivia 57.2 58.2 57.8 49.8 53.6
52.3 55.3
Colombia 60.0 58.2 56.4 58.8 54.5 52.3
55.5 54.8
Ecuador 49.9 51.1 50.2 50.5
56.4 48.3
Peru 52.9 47.4 52.6 53.8
49.0 50.9
Venezuela 42.3 44.6 41.3 47.2
53.4 50.6
Costa Rica 44.0 44.6 45.9
53.3 50.3
El Salvador 52.7 53.4
53.5
Guatemala 56.2 58.2 56.0

Honduras 51.5 51.9

Nicaragua 56.3 53.8

Panama 48.0 51.8 55.5 55.4

Mexico 48.0 54.1 54.7

Dominican Republic 50.9 53.1 50.5

Average

All countries 49.2 51.3 51.9 53.1

Countries with data

for 1986 51.3 51.7 53.2

Countries with data

for 1980 49.2 51.0 51.0 53.4

Source: Gasparini et al. (2011)

public social spending experienced since the early 1990s. Since the reform process
has coincided with the longest stretch of democratic rule in Latin America's
history, the upswing in public social expenditure and the expanded .coverage of
basic social services which this has made possible can rightly be considered to be
"democratic dividends." In contrast to this persistent improvement, labor market
and income distribution indicators have gone through two different phases: a
deterioration during the 1990-7 recovery and the lost half-decade, followed by
an improvement during the economic boom that took place at the start of the
twenty-first century.22 For the region as a whole, the improvemen~ during .the
second phase was not strong enough to entirely reverse the cumulative detenor-
ation either in income distribution that occurred from 1980 on (see Table 5.9) or,
as we will see, in the labor market since 1990. The Great Recession of 2008-9
interrupted the positive trends in these variables but, in general, it had no more
than moderate adverse effects.

Thanks to the boom that preceded the Great Recession, poverty levels, which
had been falling very gradually since 1990, dropped by more than ten percentage

22 There is a wealth of literature on these subjects. In regard to trends during the 1990s, see ECLAC
(2001a), Behrman et al. (2001) and Szekely (2001). On the recent improvement in distribution, see
Cornia (2010), Gasparini and Lustig (2011), and the compilation prepared by L6pez-Calva and Lus!lg
(2010).

248 Economic Development of Latin America

points between 2002 and 2008. It was not until 2004 that poverty levels fell below
their 1980 level, however, which means that, in terms of poverty reduction, the
region experienced not a "lost decade" but a lost quarter-century! The actual
number of poor people held at around 200 million during the 1990s and rose to
220 million during the lost half-decade, before declining by about 40 million
during the boom that occurred at the start of the twenty-first century. The
distribution of poverty also changed significantly during those decades, since
although poverty and extreme poverty rates continued to be much higher in
rural areas, an "urbanization" of poverty took place when it is measured in
absolute numbers.

Although most of the ground lost during earlier years in terms of distribution
was regained during the 2004-8 boom, the same cannot be said for labor market
indicators. This situation has been compounded by the extreme volatility of
economic growth, which has heightened Latin America's economic insecurity.
As a whole, social trends can therefore be summarized as involving increased
social spending and coverage of social services accompanied by rising job precar-
iousness and economic insecurity. The latter is reflected, for wage-earners, in the
high risk of losing their jobs and the high incidence of job turnover and, for
informal-sector workers, a higher risk of losing income.

It is important to realize that these changes were taking place at a time when the
demographic transition and the urbanization process were reaching their peak,
which means that, during the 2000s, there was less pressure on labor supply,
especially in urban areas. The decline in birth rates that had begun in the mid-
1960s translated into a total population growth rate of 1.7 percent between 1980
and 2010, which was a full percentage point less than in 1950-80, but this decline
was a persistent one, with the result that, by the end of the first decade of the
twenty-first century, the population growth rate was only slightly above 1 percent
per annum. The slowdown in the population growth rate was quite widespread,
although it was more noticeable in countries that had witnessed a population
explosion in the preceding years and came somewhat later in a number of Central
American countries (Guatemala, Honduras, and Nicaragua) and in Bolivia and
Paraguay; in turn, Costa Rica's population swelled owing to the influx of migrants
from other countries in the region (as shown by a comparison of the data given in
Table 5.10 with those shown in Table 4.9). The trend in rural-urban migration
also continued, with the result that over half of the population resides in urban
areas in all the countries and nearly three-fourths of the population does so in the
region as a whole, with a tendency for this rate to be higher in the larger
economies as part of a pattern that was already evident during the preceding
stage of development.

The labor supply expanded very rapidly from the 1970s on as a result both of
the still high growth rate of the working-age population and of the increased labor
participation rate of women as the demographic dependency rate continued to
fall. This dual effect continued to be seen until the end of the twentieth century.
According to CELADE (2006: table 11), the labor supply was still growing by as
much as 3.1 percent per year in the 1990s, which is not very different from the 3.3
percent rate that CELADE estimated for 1970-90. In the 2000s, however, as the
demographic transition neared completion and as the surge in the female labor-

Turning Back to the Market 249

Table 5.10. Population, population growth, and urbanization rates

Total population Population growth rate Urbanization rates

1980 2010 1980-2010 1980 2010

Latin America (19 countries) 349,009 572,479 1.7% 57.0 72.7

Large countries 121,672 199,992 1.7% 67.1 85.0
Brazil 69,325 110,056 1.6% 66.3 78.0
Mexico
28,094 40,519 1.2% 82.9 93.1
Southern Cone 11,174 17,094 1.4% 79.0 87.5
Argentina 2,914 3,363 0.5% 85.1 92.4
Chile
Uruguay 28,356 47,859 1.8% 64.3 78.5
17,325 28,861 1.7% 64.2 73.4
Andean 15,091 28,807 2.2% 79.0 93.6
Colombia
Peru 2,347 4,695 2.3% 42.9 66.0
Venezuela 4,586 7,453 1.6% 44.1 60.3
7,013 14,362 2.4% 33.0 57.2
Central America 3,634 7,614 2.5% 34.9 50.5
Costa Rica 3,257 5,825 2.0% 50.1 58.3
El Salvador
Guatemala 5,355 10,426 2.2% 45.5 66.4
Honduras 9,823 11,236 0.4% 68.2 77.4
Nicaragua 7,961 14,200 1.9% 47.0 65.0
1,949 2.0% 49.8 68.7
Other 3,198 3,497 2.4% 41.6 61.4
Bolivia 5,935 6,451 1.8% 37.3 68.6
Cuba 10,169
Ecuador
Panama
Paraguay
Dominican Republic

Source: ECLAC historical series

force participation rate leveled off, the growth of the labor supply dropped to a

yearly rate of 2.2 percent.
The lower demographic dependency ratio and the higher growth rate for the

economically active population relative to the total population seen during
the specific demographic transition experienced by the region in recent decades
have provided what has been dubbed in the literature as a "demographic
dividend." The benefits to be derived from this "dividend" are not automatic,
however; the economy has to create enough jobs in order to make it possible to
take advantage of that dividend. And this is why that opportunity was not seized
during the 1980s and 1990s, although it did help to bring poverty levels down. In
fact, according to Ros (2009), the decline in the dependency ratio is the main
reason for the relative trends in poverty rates seen in the Latin American countries
in 1990-2006. The positive effects of this demographic dividend were also experi-
enced in a stronger way in the 2000s, as per capita GDP for 2003-8 was similar to
the rates registered for 1967-74 (around 4 percent per annum) even though total
GDP growth remained lower than it had been during that period.

The poor performance of the labor market up to the start of the 2000s had a
devastating impact. It was the result of a number of different economic factors,
including, in particular, the slow pace of growth discussed in the preceding section

250 Economic Development of Latin America

and the effects that market reforms had on job creation. The data show that the
rate of increase in job creation was slower in the 1990s than it was in the second
half of the 1980s; what is more, unemployment rose, informal-sector employment
expanded, and wage hikes were concentrated in skilled jobs (Stallings and Weller
2001). It is worth noting that this was occurring during the years of the strongest
economic growth in the 1990s (up to 1997), which indicates that the net impact of
economic reforms on job creation was negative. These adverse trends became
more acute during the lost half-decade of 1998-2002. As the female labor"force
participation rate continued to climb (the male participation rate held steady at
around 74 percent, while the female participation rate jumped by eight percentage
points, from 38.4 percent in 1991 to 46.5 percent in 2002), the unemployment rate
skyrocketed and the informal sector of the labor market expanded rapidly (see
Table 5.11).

The deterioration in the labor market that occurred during the initial phase of
reforms was concentrated in South America, which highlights the impact of the
Latin American countries' different patterns of integration into the international
economy that were discussed earlier. As shown in Table 5.11, while employment
rates dropped and unemployment rates climbed in South America, both of these
indicators improved in Mexico and Central America. The contrast between the
"northern" and "southern" patterns was particularly evident in the manufacturing
sector. In the "northern" countries, employment in the manufacturing sector rose
at an average annual rate of 4.3 percent and accounted for 13 percent of all job
creation, whereas, in the "southern" countries, manufacturing employment
shrank by 0.1 percent per year (Stallings and Weller 2001). The maquila industry
is a key part of the explanation, given the important role it played in the growth of
the manufacturing sector in the northern part of the region during the 1990s. As
of 1999, jobs in the maquila sector accounted for between 10 percent and 40
percent of all jobs in the manufacturing sector in the northern countries (and in
some, such as Mexico and the Dominican Republic, it was a major employer as
early as the start of that decade).

The deterioration of labor market conditions during the lost half-decade was
experienced in both subregions, but it tended to take the form of open unemploy-
ment in South America, whereas in Mexico and in Central America, it was
primarily manifested in an expansion of the informal sector.

In sharp contrast to the trends seen up to the start of the twenty-first century,
the 2004-8 boom had a much more positive impact in South America in terms
of both open unemployment and formal-sector employment. The decrease in
unemployment rates was particularly steep in five South American countries
(Argentina, Colombia, Paraguay, Uruguay, and Venezuela) and in Panama,
which were the ones that had exhibited the highest rates in the past. One of the
main reasons for this was, of course, soaring commodity prices, which
strengthened the "southern" pattern of specialization. The recession that began
in late 2008 clearly curbed these growth trends, but had much less of an impact
than the two preceding crises had.

Although it clearly did improve the situation, the 2004-8 boom did not entirely
reverse the steep decline in job quality that had built up between 1990 and the start
of the twenty-first century. In particular, as of 2008 the unemployment rate
remained above the levels registered in 1990. In turn, Table 5.12 compares trends

00
0
0

"'

·"1

0 tn
''<!<

. ~ tn .-1 ("() t--.. N

·a\t--:ddt--:1.1')

'"':t"tnlO\O~lr)

00\0("-..~~0\\001""""10000000 . r--.. t..n t0 ,......~ N N

g~~~~~~~~~t;:;~~~ ·o\u)o\~1.4;).....:

·~lO"':ttlO~I.f')

ll1~<'!<'!~U:C! ....... t.f) ['... \0 ......
N000l.f)ONN ._;'-C>~dr'
• 1..1") l.f') 1./") ll) ~
V)f"()lOLOt.nlr)ll")

~~~~li)<'!OC! .NNl00\\0

~~~~~~~ · '~;) N N 0 c:i

• IJj lO 1.1) Lr) lf)

00
0
0

"'

...

0

j

252 Economic Development of Latin America

Table 5.12. Change in labor market conditions in Latin America, 1990-2008*

Open unemployment Informality Remuneration Social security
coverage

Argentina 0.5 -4.5 3.0 nq
Bolivia -0.6 -0.3 -0.7 -4.2
Brazil -9.1 -0.7
Chile 3.6 -8.9 0.1 -0.8
Colombia 0.0 -0.5 2.1
Costa Rica 1.0 0.9 nd
Ecuador -0.6 0.2 0.7 0.4
El Salvador 0.8 2.9 1.0 -6.0
Guatemala -4.5 5.4 -0.1 3.6
Honduras -0.2 3.5 0.1 2.8
Mexico -3.7 -9.4 -0.2 nd
Nicaragua 2.2 0.1 -0.5 -18.9
Panama 0.4 9.1 -0.7 -7.9
Paraguay -13.5 3.6 0.3 -4.7
Peru 0.8 1.2 0.7 3.0
0.1 -1.8 0.1 12.2
Dominican Republic -4.3 -4.2 0.6 nd
Uruguay -0.6 6.0 -0.2 4.4
Venezuela -3.1 10.7 -0.6 3.8

So11rce: ECLAC, Social Panorama Statistical Annex

' The change is calculated as the difference between the last and the first data point for each country. The years for
each country vary depending on data availability.

since 1990 in four variables that are indicative of labor market conditions. As
can be seen, a systematic improvement in all of these indicators is apparent only
in the case of Chile. In the other countries, there has been a long-term deterior-
ation in one or more of these indicators. Given the close correlation between
employment in the formal sector and access to social security, one of the
unfortunate effects of recent trends in the labor market has been a decline in
social security coverage in more than half of the countries for which information
is available. These figures corroborate the arguments made by Tokman (2007
and 2011) concerning the expansion of the informal sector of the economy
during these years, which he defines as including both informal workers as such
and wage-earners in the formal sector who do not have access to social securitf3
or an employment contract. According to his estimates (Tokman 2011), the
informal economy expanded from 58.8 percent to 64.0 percent of total urban
employment between 1990 and 2008.24

The adverse distributional trends observed in the 1990s and during the lost
half-decade also reflect a north-south pattern that very likely mirrors the ways in
which different patterns of specialization influenced labor market conditions. As
shown in Table 5.9, the situation worsened much more in South America between

23 On the subject of social security coverage, see also Uthoff (2011).
24 For 1990-2005, Garda (2007) estimates that over 55 percent of the increase in total employment
in Latin America corresponds to informal employment.

Turning Back to the Market 253

1990 and the start of the twenty-first century than it did in other parts of the
region. Even in this case, however, it was not an across-the-board phenomenon, as
the deterioration was much more marked in Argentina, Ecuador, and Venezuela
and less so in Bolivia and Uruguay, while a slight improvement was seen in Brazil.
In the northern part of the region, the setbacks in distribution began to be
reversed in Mexico and in some of the Central American countries starting in
the mid-1990s. But even in the northern part of the region, the trend was not
entirely favorable, as is shown by the figures for Costa Rica and Honduras.

It is interesting to note that some countries with more equal income distribu-
tions have witnessed a deterioration in this respect over the past few decades
(Argentina, Costa Rica, and Uruguay, in particular), while others with worse
distributions have seen an improvement (notably Brazil, but also Chile and a
number of Central American nations). There has thus been somewhat of a
convergence toward intermediate levels of inequality. Be this as it may, and
despite the recent improvement in this respect, Latin America, along with sub-
Saharan Africa, continues to be the region of the world with the highest levels of
inequality. In fact, the average levels of inequality are still somewhat higher than
they were in 1980 in the countries for which information on this variable is
available.

The ways in which structural reforms influenced income distribution have
been heatedly debated. The reforms certainly produced losers and winners, but
their net distributional impact was positive in some countries and negative in
others (see, for example, Ganuza et al. 2002), as is also true of individual compon-
ents of market reforms. No consensus on this subject has been reached.25 The
most widespread effect was an increasing wage gap between skilled and unskilled
workers in the 1990s. This was seen throughout the region, with the important
exception of Brazil. A number of authors endorse the thesis advanced by Morley
(2000), who contends that trade liberalization was the main cause of this widening
wage gap. Contributing factors included the reduction of tariffs on capital goods,
the complementarity of investment in machinery and equipment and the demand
for skilled labor, and currency appreciations (that made equipment less expensive
and increased the dollar cost of labor, which hurt the more labor-intensive
sectors). In addition, job creation in export sectors was not strong enough to
counterbalance the destruction of jobs in sectors that had once been protected and
that then had to boost their productivity to survive by initially cutting back on
their labor costs. The new jobs that were being created also tended to be less well
paid and to offer less stability (Lora 2011). Other authors, however, argue that the
widening wage gap was more a result of technological biases (as the new tech-
nologies coming into use generated a demand for more skilled labor) than of the
market reforms; this thesis would explain why this trend has been in evidence
throughout the world.

The recent reduction in inequality has been analyzed by Cornia (2010), Gas-
parini et al. (2009), Gasparini, Cruces, and Tornarolli (2011), and Gasparini and

25 Behrman et al. (2001) have argued, for example, that financial liberalization had regressive effects
that outweighed the moderately progressive impact of trade liberalization. In contrast, Morley (2000)
contends that trade liberalization had adverse effects that eclipsed the favorable impact of financial
liberalization.

254 Economic Development of Latin America

Lustig (2011), among others. This development appears to have been brought
about by a combination of short-term and structural factors, as well as by social
policy and, perhaps, strict political considerations. Short-run contributing factors
include the reversal of the severe adverse distributional shocks felt by various
countries during the lost half-decade and the reduction in the rural-urban gap
generated by the steep rise in the prices of agricultural products. The economic
boom also opened up more job opportunities for a workforce that, as mentioned
earlier, was growing more slowly than before. In addition, others were migrating
to the US and Europe in order to take advantage of the job opportunities to be
found there.

Among the factors of a more long-lasting nature that have exerted a favorable
influence, the most important one is the reversal of the sharp increase in the wage
gap separating skilled and unskilled workers. Education policy has had a great deal
to do with this outcome, both by leading to an increase in the number of years of
schooling completed by the population and by achieving a reduction, in some
respects at least, in educational inequality. According to Cornia (2010), the
reduction in educational inequality was the single most important determinant
of the improvement of income distribution in the 2000s.

The expansion of the new income-transfer programs and of conditional cash
transfers, in particular,26 along with other social assistance mechanisms, has also
helped to improve distribution, but to a lesser extent, since the amount of money
involved in these schemes is limited (no more than a few tenths of a percentage
point of these countries' national income) and, in a number of them, the coverage
of such programs is quite limited. This can be seen in the region's two largest
countries, which have implemented such transfer mechanisms on quite a large
scale. According to Gasparini and Lustig (2011), the "Oportunidades" conditional
cash transfer program has been responsible for slightly more than one fifth of the
improvement in income distribution achieved by Mexico in the 2000s, while the
broader range of transfer schemes in use in Brazil have accounted for two fifths of
the improvement in that country, although this is attributable to both social
security benefits (i.e., the non-contributory Beneficia de Prestarao Continuada, a
means-tested disability and old-age pension scheme) and to Balsa Familia
("family grant"), Brazil's conditional cash transfer program, which is now inte-
grated with other poverty-reduction policies.

Thus, although social assistance benefits are highly redistributive, the
actual amount of funds that they involve is relatively small, which is why
public expenditure on the core social policies has a greater redistributive
impact (Ocampo 2008a). The policies that have the greatest coverage, such
as primary education and, increasingly, secondary education, as well as public
health, have the strongest redistributive effect of all. Mechanisms that have
a somewhat more limited coverage, such as housing and sanitation programs,
have a slightly progressive effect, whereas those that reach no more than a
small portion of the population, such as higher education and the social security

26 Under these programs, poor households receive an income transfer from the state if parents
ensure that their school-age children attend classes and if pregnant women show up for prenatal
check-ups.

Turning Back to the Market 255

system, are regressive, although they are generally less so than the overall primary
income distribution.

The changes made in labor regimes in the course of the political changes
experienced by the region, and particularly the rise to power of a number of
left-leaning governments during the first decade of the twenty-first century, may
also have had something to do with the improvement in distribution. Even
though, as noted earlier, there had been no major liberalization of the labor
market, the earlier deterioration in income distribution occurred at a time when
the trade union movement was weakened and prevailing wage policies (especially
with regard to the minimum wage) were unfavorable for workers. In contrast,
during the 2000s, rt'(lations between employers and trade unions were more
amicable and a number of countries raised their minimum wages. Labor reforms
also changed direction in various countries and ushered in a greater degree of
protection for workers (Murillo, Ronconi, and Schrank 2011).

The impact of social policy on income distribution reflects the lagged effect of
the steady increase in public social spending over the past two decades. Infor-
mation compiled by ECLAC indicates that this item of expenditure climbed from
13.0 percent ofGDP in 1990 to 16.1 percent in 1998. Following a slowdown at the
turn of the century as a result of the impact of the lost half-decade, social spending
again picked up, rising to 18.9 percent ofGDP in 2008. What is more, as GDP has
expanded-at a quite rapid pace during some periods-these percentages trans-
late into even larger amounts in absolute terms. Over these past two decades, the
increase in social spending has been sharper in countries where it was initially
lower, which means that, in addition, the differences between the relative levels of
social spending as a percentage of GDP has tended to narrow across the region.
Nonetheless, both in the early 1990s and in 2008, Argentina, Brazil, Costa Rica,
and Uruguay had above-average levels of social spending. The greatest increases
were seen in Brazil and Colombia, among the larger countries, and in El Salvador
and Paraguay, among the smaller nations.

The increase in social spending has translated into a steady improvement in
educational and health indicators, as well as in the coverage of water and sewerage,
among other services, although, clearly, with differences from one country to
another. The inroads being made in these fields place the region above the average
for developing countries and at comparable or higher rankings than other
developing regions with similar per capita income levels (East Asia), with the
notable exception of some health indicators (e.g., maternal mortality) in certain
countries (see Table 5.13). This is also reflected in the trend in the region's human
development indices, although, as seen in Chapter 1, somewhat less progress has
been made in this respect than during the stage of state-led industrialization.

However, these advances should not be overestimated. School dropout rates
continue to pose a challenge for countries striVing to ensure universal coverage for
primary education. Furthermore, the distribution of access to higher education
has not improved and has actually worsened in some countries, and there are
serious problems in terms of the quality of education at all levels. There are
still enormous problems in terms of public health as well, with high rates of
maternal mortality in some countries, as well as inadequate treatment of various
transmissible diseases (HIVIAIDS, malaria, and tuberculosis) and chronic non-
transmissible diseases whose incidence is on the rise (cardiovascular conditions,

256 Economic Development of Latin America

Table 5.13. Progress toward millennium development goals

Latin America and East Asia Developing
the Caribbean Countries

1990 2007 1990 2007 1990 2007

Underweight children 13% 6% 17% 7% 33% 26%
under-five years of age1
Population below minimum level 13% 8% 16% 10% 20% 17%
of dietary energy requirements
Net enrollment ratio 86.7% 94.9% 98.0% 95.2% 79.6% 88.1%
Primary 58.7% 70.2% 60.7% 69.0% 45.4% 52.6%
21.5% 31.3% 13.3% 24.2% 10.9% 17.4%
Secondarf
Tertiarf 97.0% 97.0% 94.0% 99.0% 87.0% 95.0%
Ratio girls to boys 106.0% 107.0% 97.0% 101.0% 90.0% 94.0%
Primary 113.0% 119.0% 55.0% 96.0% 78.0% 96.0%
Secondarf 103
Tertiarf 55 24 45 22 74
Under-five mortality rate
Maternal mortality ratio4 180 130 95 50 480 450
(per 1,000 births)
Proportion of births attended 68% 87% 71% 98% 47% 61%
by skilled health personnel
Proportion of population 84% 92% 68% 88% 71% 84%
using: 5 68% 79% 48% 65% 41% 53%
Drinking water
Sanitation facilities

1 Data for population below minimum level of dietary requirements correspond to the latest available: 1990/1992
and 2008.

2 Data for secondary correspond to 1999/2000 and 2006. Japan is included in the data of enrollment for East Asia.
3 Corresponds to gross enrollment rate. Given the variance in the length of programs ~t this educational level, it is

difficult to determine adequate age groups. Therefore, net enrollment rate in tertiary education is not relevant. The
data correspond to 1999/2000 and 2006.
4 The information for 2007 corresponds to 2005, which is the latest available.
5 The information for 2007 corresponds to 2005, which is the latest available.

Source: United Nations and UNESCO

diabetes, and cancer). In addition, high levels of violence are also reflected in the
health indicators of some countries. Furthermore, although progress h11s been
made in providing suitable housing, a significant proportion of dwellings are still
made of poor-quality materials and a still considerable portion of the population
hKks sanitary fittings and connections (IDB 2008a).

The area of social policy in which the least progress has been made or in which
there have been outright setbacks is unquestionably that of social security cover-
age, defined in a broad sense (old-age pensions, health-care coverage, unemploy-
ment benefits, etc.). In this respect, there is a clear contrast to be drawn between
the period of state-led industrialization and more recent decades. During the
former period, as was seen in the preceding chapter, a segmented welfare state
provided coverage primarily to workers in the formal sector of the economy.
During the more recent period, these social security mechanisms have either
stagnated or actually been rolled back, but, at the same time, there has been
considerable progress in the provision of social assistance in the form of condi-
tional cash transfers, and nutrition and employment programs (Ferreira and

Turning Back to the Market 257

Robalino 2011). The main problem in connection with social security is that
benefits are basically tied to formal employment (a situation referred to in
Chapter 4 as the "Bismarckian model"). This situation is at odds with trends in
the labor market in recent decades, where the informal sector accounts for an
increasing proportion of employment and job instability has increased.

The countries of the region can be divided into three camps in this respect,
according to Uthoff (2011). The first group, where the informal sector is very
extensive, includes Bolivia, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Nicar-
agua, Peru, and Paraguay. These countries have relatively young populations and
a high dependency ratio that reflects the large number of young people and
informal workers. Social security coverage for employees is below 30 percent.
The second group is made up of Colombia, Mexico, the Dominican Republic,
Panama, and Venezuela. The birth rate has declined in these countries, and this is
reflected in striking changes in the age structure of their populations. Social
security coverage for employees is around 50 percent. Finally, countries such as
Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Costa Rica, and Uruguay make up the last group. They
have older populations and a high dependency ratio that is attributable to the
presence of a large number of economically inactive older adults and young
people. Social security coverage for employees amounts to over 60 percent.
These are the countries that could potentially act as welfare states. As was
discussed in Chapter 4, they are also the countries that were the first to begin to
make the transition to modern welfare systems.

What this shows is that the entirely contributory social security systems that
were developed during the stage of state-led industrialization are exclusionary. In
addition, given the state's limited ability to build more comprehensive benefits,
firms and households have sought out ways of doing this for themselves or ways of
utilizing market mechanisms for this purpose. The explicit inclusion of the private
sector in social security systems can leverage the utilization of the market to fulfill
social security objectives, but this approach also has exclusionary effects.
A consensus has therefore been reached as to the fact that progress in this area
will have to be based on non-contributory government-financed mechanisms and
on the design of innovative systems for incorporating informal-sector workers.27
This is, therefore, the area of social policy in which the most serious failings of all
the development models used so far in the region are most apparent.

27 ECLAC (2006a), Levy (2008), and Uthoff (2011) and others have proposed reforms of this type.

6

By Way of Conclusion

The History and Challenges of Latin American
Development

Throughout this book, special emphasis has been placed on four aspects of the
economic history of Latin America. The first has to do with the region's achieve-
ments in terms of economic development, which, when compared with those of
other world regions, reveal some strengths and some failings. The second aspect is
the economic instability associated with the region's patterns of international
specialization, which even to this day revolve around natural resources and the
instability of its access to international financing. The third has been the slow pace
at which the region has developed modern political and economic institutions and
the high degree of variability in economic policies and development paradigms
that has gone along with this. The fourth is the degree of inequality existing in
Latin America, which is faced with more serious problems in this respect than
other regions. Let us take a look at how these different aspects are linked to one
another.

DEVELOPMENT AND INEQUALITY

There is no question about the fact that the region has developed. This is reflected
in increases in per capita GDP, improvements in human development indicators,
and reductions in poverty levels. The fact remains, however, that these processes
have been uneven in terms of both time and geography.

The two centuries covered by this analysis have been divided into four different
subperiods in order to help us see how the pace of progress has varied: (1) the
decades following the time when most of the countries won their independence;
(2) the closing decades of the nineteenth century and the first three decades of the
twentieth, which was when the first wave of globalization took place and develop-
ment in the region was driven by commodity exports; (3) the period of state-led
industrialization (this term being preferred over the misleading expression of
"import-substitution industrialization"), which occurred in the intervening period
between two major crises (the Great Depression of the 1930s and the "lost decade"
of the 1980s); and (4) the period of market reform, which began in the 1980s and

By Way of Conclusion 259

has coincided with the second wave of globalization at the international level.
Because Latin America is such a diverse region, these phases did not start or end at
the same time in every country, and the exact divisions between these periods may
therefore differ in some cases.

Generally speaking, the first phase was a time when the region lost ground
relative to what is now the industrialized world but gained ground vis-a-vis most
of the countries that make up what is considered to be the developing world. The
last period was also a time when the region lost ground, but in this case it was in
relation not only to the industrialized world but also to the world average and, in
particular, the developing countries of Asia.

In contrast, during the phase of commodity-export-led growth, Latin America
was-along with central and southern Europe-one of the peripheral regions that
was most successful in joining in the wave of economic growth. This enabled it to
become part of what might be described as a global "middle class." During the
period of state-led industrialization, Latin America's economy continued to grow
at above-average rates and to expand its share of world production. Nonetheless,
during neither of these relatively successful periods did it make any significant
progress in closing the wide gap that as early as 1870 was already separating it
from the developed world. What is more, during the industrialized countries'
"golden age" (1950-73), it fell further behind Western Europe. Looking at the
second and fourth periods-i.e., the first and second waves of globalization-we
can see that Latin America was clearly a winner during the first wave but was
unable to fully take advantage of the second, during which it again lost ground in
relative terms.

Progress was slower to come in the social arena. The deplorable state of the
education system at the start of the twentieth century, even in the countries that
were leading the regional development process, attests to this fact. The region's
human development indicators did begin to improve in the third decade of the
twentieth century and rose the most during the period of state-led industrializa-
tion. These indicators remained more or less constant relative to the industrialized
world during the phase of market reforms, although the education sector con-
tinued to make headway. The greatest progress in reducing poverty during the
twentieth century was also made during the period of state-led industrialization.
After a "lost quarter century" (rather than simply a lost decade) in this respect,
which had begun in the 1980s, the most promising substantive progress made in
reducing poverty came between 2002 and 2008. This was also a time during which
income distribution improved in many of the Latin American countries. (These
improvements may have continued to be made since then, but we do not yet have
solid evidence to confirm that conjecture.)

The history of how the region became such an unequal one is complex and
diverse and does not follow a single region-wide pattern. The colonial legacy of
highly economically and socially segmented societies continues to weigh upon the
region's development process. This dynamic has been highlighted by the Latin
American structuralist school of thought since the 1950s and, more recently, has
been underscored by the new institutionalist thinkers. The much-discussed fact
that the Latin American countries have the worst income distribution in the entire
world is glaring proof of this. But this situation cannot be entirely laid at the door
of the region's colonial past, because the trends and events that have taken shape

260 Economic Development of Latin America

between the collapse of colonial rule and the present day have also had a major
influence that has also differed substantially across countries.

Some of the processes that have had a negative and more or less region-wide
effect on income distribution include the first wave of globalization, the 1980s
debt crisis, and the initial stages of the economic liberalization efforts of the late
twentieth century. For the countries with large labor surpluses, the downward
pressure on wages that this situation exerted during a large part of the twentieth
century also had negative effects in terms of distribution. These effects were
compounded by the measures enacted by many of the region's former military
dictatorships.

Positive forces have also been at work, however. The greatest step forward in
social equality was clearly the abolition of slavery, which was a long time in
coming in some countries (Brazil and Cuba). It took longer to do away with the
various forms of rural servitude, which were quite prevalent even in the early
twentieth century in most of the Latin American countries and continued to
influence labor relations for far longer. Advancing urbanization did a great deal
to open up new opportunities for people who had been subject to the strict social
segmentation characteristic of rural areas. The belated advances experienced in
the education system also helped to create a more level playing field, and this has
been reflected in a better pattern of income distribution in the early twenty-first
century. There is still a great deal of ground to cover in this respect, however, as is
demonstrated by the failings and inequalities in the quality of education found in
the vast majority of Latin American countries.

Other processes that have positive effects in terms of equity have been unevenly
distributed throughout the region. The large flows of European migrants that
went to the Southern Cone depressed wages at first, but in the long run had
positive distributional effects. One of the reasons for this was that these immi-
grants brought skills, knowledge, and especially institutions (including trade
unionism) along with them that helped to spread the benefits of development.
The most positive impact of this process was felt during the early stages of the
state-led industrialization phase. These gains were reversed, however, in the 1960s
and 1970s by bloody dictatorships that weakened the institutional mechanisms
which had served as a foundation for gains in equity. Other countries have made
institutional changes that promote equity, as occurred in Costa Rica in the mid-
twentieth century and in Cuba as a result of the 1959 revolution. Agrarian reforms
of widely varying scopes were less effective than expected in redistributing land,
but they did help to combat forms of labor servitude that were still in use in rural
areas. The combination of shrinking rural labor surpluses and improving levels of
education led to improvements in distribution in some countries during the 1960s
and 1970s.

What net effect did these trends have on income and wealth distribution? The
historical trends in this respect vary a great deal, and there is not enough infor-
mation to determine exactly what impact they had, but we can discern four
different phases. The first was the deterioration that occurred up to the start of
the twentieth century or even later in economies that had labor surpluses. This
was followed by an improvement in distribution which occurred earlier (starting
in the 1920s) in the Southern Cone, thanks to the institutional forces mentioned
above, and later on (in the 1960s or 1970s) in others (Colombia, Costa Rica,

By Way of Conclusion 261

Mexico, and Venezuela), although there were some countries, such as Brazil,
where this failed to occur at all. The third phase, in which distribution deterior-
ated, began in the Southern Cone countries but then spread to others in the late
twentieth century in the wake of the lost decade and market reforms. Finally, more
or less two thirds of the countries have witnessed an improvement in distribution
in the first decade of the twenty-first century; in some of them, this improvement
started in the latter years of the twentieth. From a long-term perspective, inequal-
ity in income distribution in Latin America, which is widely recognized as being
highly structural in nature, may actually be worse today than it was before the
region experienced the first burst of economic growth in the second half of the
nineteenth century. In fact, despite the improvement in distribution that occurred
in the early years of the twenty-first century, the mean level of inequality in the
region is higher than it was in 1980.

The region's inequality is also evident in geographical terms. Even during the
years following independence, when economic performance was generally poor,
some countries made headway, such as those of the Southern Cone and perhaps
Costa Rica, and there were also some successful regions within countries, such as
northern Mexico and Antioquia in Colombia. Extensive growth was also observed
in the two economies (Brazil and Cuba) that continued to rely on the horrific
institution of slave labor-partly because there was no break with the colonial
system as such. During the second of these stages, this divergence in development
processes deepened, at least until the First World War. By that time, the countries
of the Southern Cone and, to a lesser extent, Cuba, had increased their edge over
the rest of the region. From that point on, there was a tendency toward conver-
gence as the other countries began to become more successful and the leading
nations' pace of growth began to slow, although there were a few countries
(Bolivia and Nicaragua, in particular) that were left behind. This process of
regional convergence came to a halt during the lost decade of the 1980s, however,
and in more recent decades has given way to a growing divergence once again.

In sum, the situation in terms of social equity has been somewhat dishearten-
ing, since the gap separating the region from the more developed countries has
grown at the same time that the inequalities within the individual countries of the
region have also increased. The only bright spot has been a decline in inequalities,
over the long term, among Latin American countries.

MACROECONOMIC INSTABILITY, INSTITUTION -BUILDING,
AND DEVELOPMENT PARADIGMS

The fact that the leading countries in the region began to grow more slowly in the
aftermath of the First World War demonstrates the variability of Latin American
development. As part of this pattern, countries of the region have tended to grow
rapidly for extended periods of time. During these periods they have narrowed the
income gap separating them from industrialized countries. But these growth
spurts have then given way to equally long periods during which this gap widens
again. This process has been described as one of truncated convergence-i.e.,

262 Economic Development of Latin America

periods of convergence that are cut short and followed by increasing divergence.
Cuba is perhaps the first and most prominent example: after having been one of
the leading export success stories in the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries,
its per capita income levels remained almost entirely flat from the 1920s on. Much
the same thing occurred in the Southern Cone, which forged ahead of the rest
until the First World War, but then lost ground. This was particularly the case in
Argentina, which was one of the greatest development success stories during the
first wave of globalization. Following in its footsteps was Venezuela, which was
Latin America's star performer from the 1920s to the 1960s, thanks to its oil boom
and its ability to spread the benefits reaped from that boom, although this period
was followed by one of relative retrogression. Brazil and Mexico, the "stars" of the
period of state-led industrialization, followed this same path soon after, lapsing
into a period of fairly slow growth starting in the 1980s. The absence of "growth
miracles" but also of major crises is the curious secret of Colombia, which seems
to have found the key to a way of achieving a moderate but steady development
path. This more stable pattern can also be discerned, although somewhat less
markedly, in Costa Rica and Panama, which have been two of the three most
successful smaller countries in the long run (the other one being Uruguay, which
has experienced sharper fluctuations in its development process).

As can be seen from the above, past trends in development and in income
inequality have not moved in parallel with one another. In the countries of the
Southern Cone, for example, the greatest improvements in income distribution
took place during a time when economic development was lagging. At other
times, periods of slow growth have had adverse distributional effects, with the
most conspicuous example being the lost decade of the 1980s. In other cases,
periods of strong growth have been coupled with deteriorations in income
distribution (the first wave of globalization in most of the countries of the region
and the Brazilian "miracle," for example), while, in still others, growth and gains
in equity have gone hand in hand (as in the boom of2004-8 and perhaps in recent
years as well).

The most frequent and widespread fluctuations have been associated with the
Latin American economies' external vulnerability and the resulting volatility of
economic growth. The overriding factor throughout the two centuries analyzed in
this book has been the region's dependency on commodities, whose prices have
been highly volatile, especially between the First World War and the Great
Depression and since the early or mid-1970s. This situation has been com-
pounded by the even greater volatility associated with the countries' highly
irregular and procyclical access to external financing, which has been at the root
of some of the region's most abrupt business cycles, as in the boom of the second
half of the 1920s, which was followed by the deep downturn and the defaults of
almost all the debtor countries in the 1930s. The boom of the second half of the
1970s, which gave way to the lost decade of the 1980s, is another example. This
last crisis has been the most sever~ one experienced by Latin America as a region,
not only because of the strength and duration of some of the shocks generated by
international markets (the higher relevant interest rates and lower commodity
prices that were triggered by this crisis lasted for more than two decades), but also
because the region was faced with a true creditors' cartel that had the backing of
the leading developed countries and international financial institutions. As a

By Way of Conclusion 263

result, this was the first time that the countries of the region could not resort
(except for very brief periods) to the primary mechanism that had been used to
manage financial crises in the past: external debt default.

This economic instability has been coupled with institutional instability and
significant shifts in development policies and paradigms. Institutional instability
was one of the most serious problems that the countries faced after they had won
independence. This problem was overcome by some of the countries later on, in
the nineteenth century, although in many cases they did so by resorting to
authoritarian regimes. Revolutions or major social conflicts occurred in all of
the countries whose economies were growing slowly during the period of state-led
industrialization, and disruptions of this sort swept over most of the Central
American region (with the exceptions of Costa Rica and Panama) in the 1970s
and 1980s. As the experiences of the late nineteenth and most of the twentieth
centuries indicate, there has been a tendency to guarantee institutional stability
by resorting to authoritarian regimes throughout the region's history. Thus, the
triumph of economic liberalism, although much more gradual than what had been
expected following independence, was not matched (except in a handful of coun-
tries and, even then, only in some respects) by a victory of political liberalism. It has
n~t been until more recent times, since the 1980s, that the region has, for the first
time in its history, witnessed a convergence of economic and political liberalism.

The major shifts in Latin America's development paradigms have perhaps been
the issue that has received the most attention in traditional economic historiog-
raphy. We use traditional typologies as a starting point here, but with a number of
significant variations. As we have seen, in a number of the major economies,
during the phase of commodity-export-led growth the development of a dynamic
export sector was not viewed as being opposed to modern industrialization under
high tariff protection. Indeed, at that time, Latin America-along with the United
States and Australasia-had the highest tariffs in the world. Although the basic
rationale was to obtain public revenues, many of the countries in the region could
not resist the temptation to use tariffs as a form of protection as well. Be this as it
may, the structural changes that took place during this stage of development were
quite moderate and left Latin America lagging far behind in terms of its educa-
tional system and its level of industrialization. As a result, Latin America played a
very marginal role, and even then only belatedly, in what has been called the
second industrial revolution, after having played a similarly marginal part in the

first.
During the stage of state-led industrialization, Latin America moved closer to

the mixed European model and was, accordingly, less statist than the rest of the
developing world-a fact which is often overlooked in the literature. In addition,
in a number of middle-sized and especially many small countries, the industri-
alization process was overlaid upon what continued to be a fundamentally
commodity-export-led growth model. Even in the largest countries, commodity
export sectors continued to play an important role, which is why industrialist
interests never did achieve the hegemony that they had in the European countries
that were latecomers to industrialization or the hegemony that they would have
later on in East Asia. Finally, in the more recent period, apart from some steps to
open up the economy to trade and foreign capital that were taken by virtually all
the countries, the way in which economic liberalization took place varied quite a

264 Economic Development of Latin America

bit among Latin American countries. This is why we have preferred to speak about
"market reforms" rather than about a uniform "neo-liberal" paradigm.

Much of what has been discussed here makes it clear that the "Black Legend"
about the period of state-led industrialization that has been propagated by the
orthodox school of economic thought is founded more upon ideology than on an
examination of the economic and social outcomes of that paradigm. This stage
was not only the period of the most prolonged, rapid, and stable economic growth,
but was also the period when poverty was reduced the most sharply and major
advances were made in terms of human development. We have also argued that
the debt crisis of the 1980s was not generated by the failings of that paradigm, but
by the abrupt boom-bust cycles of external financing that the Latin American
economy experienced in the 1970s and 1980s. The fact that the economies of the
Southern Cone, in which the liberalization cycle had already begun, were hit the
hardest is perhaps the best evidence of this. However we must be careful not to
create a myth about the success of the state-led industrialization model either, nor
should we embrace the illusion that the region could return to a past era that had
its origins in the collapse of the first wave of globalization and that would therefore
be an anachronism during the second wave of globalization that we are experi-
encing today.

The main defect of that paradigm was its inability to build a solid technological
base. That inability was deeply entrenched, as it was rooted in the lag in Latin
America's industrial development during the first wave of globalization, cumula-
tive lags in education, and the even greater backwardness in terms of the con-
struction of a scientific-technological base of its own. Starting in the mid-1970s,
this problem was compounded by the reversal of the industrialization process
while the region was still at an early stage in its development. This turnaround led
to the slowing or even reversal of the upward trend in productivity levels that most
Latin American economies had been experiencing; furthermore, this reversal took
place despite the advances made in some specific firms and sectors under market
reforms. In our view, the early truncation of the convergence of the leading
countries in the region was essentially a result of these structural phenomena.
An additional factor in the Southern Cone countries was that the combination of
their domestic-market orientation and the underdevelopment of their export
sectors proved to be a fatal flaw during the period of state-led industrialization.
In the other case of truncated convergence-that of Cuba-the problem was quite
possibly just the opposite-i.e., an excessive e)\port orientation.

An "anti-export bias" was a problem for many of the larger economies during
the period of state-led industrialization. Policymakers were aware of this problem,
however, and consequently began moving toward a mixed model in the mid-
1960s that combined export protection with export diversification and regional
integration. The advances made by export sectors have been the great success
story of the market reform phase, but the benefits of this process in terms of
overall development have yet to be fully realized.

It should be added that, while the concept of an "anti-export bias" is valid in
some respects, we find no solid basis for stating that the phase of state-led
industrialization generated an "anti-agricultural bias" or a general lack of macro-
economic discipline. In fact, the agricultural sector grew more during this phase of

By Way of Conclusion 265

development than it has done after market reforms, although this comparison is of
the averages of widely varying experiences. As for the question of a lack of
macroeconomic discipline, we have shown that a propensity to inflation was not
in evidence almost anywhere except the Southern Cone and Brazil up to the early
1970s and that there was no widespread lack of fiscal discipline until external
financing was made available in abundance during the second half of that decade.
Runaway inflation was more of an effect, rather than a cause, of the debt crisis of
the 1980s. The achievements made in these two areas in recent decades are, of
course, attributable to successful macroeconomic management. This has been a
net historical gain for Brazil and the Southern Cone, and a return to the condi-
tions that were typical up until the 1960s for the rest of the countries.

PRESENT CHALLENGES FROM A HISTORICAL

PERSPECTIVE

At least four major lessons for the future can be drawn from Latin America's
history. The first has to do with the region's achievements in the area of macro-
economic management. Its accomplishments in terms of inflation and fiscal
sustainability need to be consolidated, but policymakers are also faced with the
immense challenge of managing the Latin American economies' long-standing
vulnerability to external shocks. The response to the 2008-9 global crisis was in
many ways a positive one for Latin America: there was no external or domestic
financial crisis in any country and inflation did not spiral out of control. However,
it proved impossible to avoid a sharp initial recession in the region, though this
was, fortunately, turned around quite rapidly, with the region (and especially
South America) registering a positive growth rate in 2010 and 2011. Furthermore,
the boom that preceded the most recent global crisis and the return of capital
flows and high commodity prices since mid-2009 have shown that there is still a
great deal to be learned about handling economic booms and, in particular, about
averting cyclical currency appreciations (which make even less sense in today's
export-oriented economies), upswings in public-sector spending during times of
abundance, and especially the steep increases in lending and private-sector
spending that typically occur during such periods.

The second lesson relates to economic growth, which has been a frustrating
issue for a majority of Latin American countries during the market reform phase.
History tells us that high growth rates cannot be attained solely on the back of a
sound macroeconomic situation or patterns of specialization based on static
comparative advantages. Proactive production policies-which were explicitly
excluded from public-sector agendas during the market reform phase-are also
needed. And there is an even more glaring need to fast-forward the design of
proactive technology policies, which were also seriously neglected during the
period of state-led industrialization. This effort should be coupled with a consoli-
dation of the progress made in education and the introduction of measures to
address the education system's failings, especially in terms of quality and of the

266 Economic Development of Latin America

alignment of curricula with the skills and capacities required in order to change
the region's production patterns.

The third lesson refers to institution-building and particularly one dimension
of that process which has long been a subject of controversy: the relationship
between the state and the market. A related facet of the Latin American
development process has been the region's tendency toward rentism, which
has been manifested both as a dependence on the rents afforded by natural
resource endowments and as a reliance on those to be derived from a "special
relationship" with the state. Education and the development of technology (the
two policy areas on which we focused in the preceding paragraph) are the best
way to overcome this Latin American institutional trait. International experi-
ence tells us that an appropriate mix of the state and the market is vital, but it
also shows us that there is no single design that is best for achieving positive
synergies between the two.

Contrary to what many have thought in recent decades, the greatest
weakn~sses in this area may be in the development of the state's capabilities.
This question was also of importance in the early years of the Latin Ameri-
can republics. The greatest strides in this regard were made during the phase
of state-led industrialization, even though the state that was created at that
time often fell victim to its own inefficiencies and its inability to stand up to
powerful interest groups. Latin America clearly fell farther and farther behind
not only the industrialized nations but also the Asian countries (where the
development of the state has deep historical roots). History shows us that
forward progress is perfectly feasible, however. When strong policy initiatives
are taken, they make important inroads. Examples include the creation of
social-service delivery mechanisms and the development of the production
sector during the period of state-led industrialization, the development of
strong finance ministries and social assistance programs during the market
reform phase, and the steps taken to build strong central banks during both
periods. Education and technological development should therefore be at the
center of state reform efforts in the future.

The last and most important lesson has to do with the enormous social debt
that Latin America has built up over its history. The colonial legacy of extreme
economic and social inequality, which has been analyzed in classic works of Latin
American economic historiography, has been perpetuated and, in some cases,
heightened in subsequent periods of the region's history, which have added new
dimensions to this phenomenon. In the past few decades, more ground has been
lost in this respect, and an entire quarter-century was lost in terms of poverty
reduction before advances again began to be made in 2002-8. What is more, the
contrast between these results and the advances made in human development
indicate that social policy is not enough, in itself, to made headway in terms of
social equity-not as long as the economic system continues to produce and
reproduce high levels of inequality in income distribution.

Herein lies Latin America's greatest historical debt. The return to an equity
agenda, the new discourse around "social cohesion," and the forward movement
in this area observed during the first decade of the twenty-first century are all
promising signs. The future will show whether or not these trends herald the first
steps toward correcting the most grievous aberration of the Latin American

By Way of Conclusion 267

development process. As history has shown us, however, these advances will not
be lasting ones unless they are combined with the changes in education, technol-
ogy, and production that are needed in order for the region to be able to integrate
itself into the global economy in a more dynamic manner while at the same time
deepening the integration of its own economies and societies.

1
i
I

References

Abreu, M. de Paiva (2000). "Argentina and Brazil During the 1930s: The Impact of British
and US International Economic Policies," in R. Thorp (ed.), An Economic History of
Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 2: Latin America in the 1930s: The Role of the
Periphery in the World Crisis. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with St Antony's
College, Oxford, 127-42 (ch. 6).

-Bevilaqua, A., and Pinho, D. M. (2000). "Import Substitution and Growth in Brazil,
1890s-1970s," in E. Cirdenas, J. A. Ocampo, and R. Thorp (eds), An Economic History of
Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 3: Industrialization and the State in Latin Amer-
ica: The Postwar Years. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with St Antony's College,
Oxford, 154-75 (ch. 6).

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. (2003). "Disease and Development in Histor-
ical Perspective." Journal of the European Economic Association, 1/2-3: 397-405.

-(2005). "Institutions as the Fundamental Cause of Long-Run Growth", in Aghion, Ph.
and S. Durlauf, S. N., Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1A, Amesterdam: Elsevier
North-Holland, 385-472.

Acefta, M. P. and Reis, J. (eds) (2000). Monetary Standards in the Periphery: Paper, Silver
and Gold, 1854-1933. New York: St. Martin's Press.

Akyiiz, Y. (ed.) (2003). Developing Countries and World Trade: Performance and Prospects.
Geneva, Penang, and London: UNCTAD, Third World Network, Zed Books.

Allen, R. C. (1994). "Real Incomes in the English-Speaking World, 1879-1913," in
G. Grantham and M. MacKinnon (eds), Labour Market Evolution: Essays in the Eco-
nomic History of Market Integration, Wage Flexibility and the Employment Relation.
London: Routledge, 107-38.

Altimir, 0. (1996). "Economic Development and Social Equity: A Latin American Perspec-
tive." Journal of Interamerican Studies and World Affairs, 38/2-3: 47-71.

- (1997). "Desigualdad, empleo y pobreza en America Latina: Efectos del ajuste y del
cambia en el estilo de desarrollo." Desarrollo Econ6mico, 37/145: 3-30.

-(2001). "Long-Term Trends of Poverty in Latin American Countries." Estudios de
Econom(a, 28/1: 115-55.

-and Devlin, R. (1993). "Una resefta de Ia moratoria de Ia deuda en America Latina," in
0. Altimir and R. Devlin (eds), Moratoria de Ia deuda en America Latina. Mexico: Fonda
de Cultura Econ6mica, 13-81 (ch. 1).

Alvarez, J. (2007). "Instituciones, cambia tecnol6gico y distribuci6n del ingreso. Una
comparaci6n del desempefto econ6mico de Nueva Zelanda y Uruguay (1870-1940)."
Montevideo: Facultad de Ciencias Sociales, Unidad Multidisciplinaria, Programa de
Historia Econ6mica y Social. (Tesis de Maestria).

-Bertola, L., and Porcile, G. (eds) (2007). Primos ricos y empobrecidos. Montevideo: Fin
de Siglo.

Anderson, K. and Valdes A. (2008). "Introduction and Summary," in K. Anderson and
A. Valdes (eds), Distortions to Agricultural Incentives in Latin America. Washington,
DC: World Bank, 1-58.

Andrews, G. D. (2004). Afro-Latin America 1800-2000. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Aravena, C., Badia-Mir6, M., Hofman A. A., Hurtado, C., and Jofre, J. (2010). "Growth,

Productivity and Information and Communications Technologies in Latin America,
1950-2005," in M. Cimoli, A. A. Hofman, and N. Mulder (eds), Innovation and
Economic Development: The Impact of Information and Communication Technologies
in Latin America. Cheltenham (UK): Edward Elgar Publishing, 118-38.

1 References 269

Arze Aguirre, R. (1999). "Notas para una Historia del siglo XX en Bolivia," in F. Campero
Prudencio (ed.), Bolivia en el siglo XX: La forma cion de Ia Bolivia contemporanea. La Paz:

Editorial Offsets Boliviana, 47-66.
Astorga, P. (2000). "Industrialization in Venezuela, 1936-1983: The Problem of Abun-

dance," in E. Cardenas, J. A. Ocampo, and R. Thorp (eds), An Economic History of
Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 3: Industrialization and the State in Latin Amer-
ica: The Postwar Years. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with St Antony's College,

Oxford, 154-75 (ch. 6).
-Berges, A. R., and FitzGerald, V. (2005). "The Standard of Living in Latin America

During the Twentieth Century." Economic History Review, 54/4: 765-96.
---(2011). "Productivity growth in Latin America over the long run." Review of

Income and Wealth, 57/2: 203-23.
-and FitzGerald, V. (1998). "Apendice Estadistico," in R. Thorp, Progreso, Pobreza y

Exclusion: Una Histbria Econ6mica de America Latina en el Siglo XX. Washington, DC:

Inter-American Development Bank and European Union, 327-85.
Bacha, E. and Dlaz-Alejandro, C. F. (1982). International Financial Intermediation: A Long

and Tropical View. Essays in International Finance, 147. Princeton: Princeton Univer-
sity, Department of Economics. Reprinted in Andres Velasco (ed.) .(1988). Trade,
Development and the World Economy: Selected Essays ofCarlos Dfaz-A/e;andro. Oxford:

Basil Blackwell, ch. 8.
Badia-Mir6, M. and Carreras-Marin, A. (2012). "Latin America and Its Main Trading

Partners, 1860-1930: Did the First World War Affect Geographical Patterns?" in
C. Yanez and A. Carreras (eds), The Economies of Latin America: New Cliometric

Data. London: Pickering & Chatto. ·

Bairoch, P. (1993). Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes. Chicago: Chicago

University Press.
-and Etemad, B. (1985). Structure par produits des exportations du Tiers Monde:

1830-1937. Publications du Centre d'histoire economique internationale de l'Universite

de Geneve, 1. Geneve: Droz.
Balassa, B., Bueno, G. M., Kuczynski, P. P., and Simonsen, M. H. (1986). Toward Renewed

Economic Growth in Latin America. Washington, DC: Institute of International

Economics.
Balbis, J. (2005). "La evoluci6n del precio de Ia tierra en Uruguay (1914-1924)." Quantum,

2/5: 114-41.
Baptista, A. (2006). Bases cuantitativas de Ia economfa venezolana, 1830-2002. Caracas:

Fundaci6n Empresas Polar.
-and Mommer, B. (1987). El petr6leo en el pensamiento econ6mico venezolano: Un

ensayo. Caracas: IESA.
Bates, R.H. (1997). Open-Economy Politics: The Political Economy of the World Coffee

Trade. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Bates, R. H., Coatsworth, J. H., and Williamson, J. G. (2007). "Lost Decades: Postindepen-

dence Performance in Latin America and Africa." Journal ofEconomic History, 67: 917-43.
Bauer, A. (1986). "Rural Spanish America, 1870-1930", in L. Bethell (ed.), The Cambridge

History ofLatin America, vol. 4: c.1870 to 1930. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,

151-86.
Beck, T. and Demirgiic;:-Kunt, A. (2009). "Financial Institutions and Markets Across

Countries and Over Time: Data and Analysis." World Bank Policy Research Working

Paper, No. 4943, May.
Behrman, J., Birdsall, N., and Szekely, M. (2001). "Pobreza, Desigualdad y Liberalizaci6n

Comercial y Financiera en America Latina," in E. Ganuza, R. Paes de Barros, L. Taylor,
and R. Vos (eds), Liberalizaci6n, desigualdad y pobreza: America Latina y el Caribe en los
90. Buenos Aires: EUDEBA; Universidad de Buenos Aires; PNUD.

270 References

Belini, C. and Rougier, M. (2008). El Estado Empresario en Ia Industria Argentina: Con-
formaci6n y crisis. Buenos Aires: Manantial (Cuadernos Argentinas).

Berry, A. (1998). Confronting the Income Distribution Threat in Latin America: Poverty,
Economic Reforms, and Income Distribution in Latin America. Boulder, CO: Lynne
Rienner.

Bertino, M. and Tajam, H. (1999). El PBI de Uruguay 1900-1955. Montevideo: Universidad
de la Republica, Facultad de Ciencias Economicas y Administracion, Instituto de
Economia.

Bertola, L. (1991). La Industria Manufacturera Uruguaya, 1913-1961: Un enfoque sectorial
de su crecimiento, fluctuaciones y crisis. Montevideo: CIEDUR; Facultad de Ciencias
Sociales.

- (2000). Ensayos de Historia Econ6mica de Uruguay y Ia region en Ia economfa mundial,
1870-1990. Montevideo: Trike; CSIC.

- (2005). "A 50 aftos de la curva de Kuznets: crecimiento econ6mico y distribucion del
ingreso en Uruguay y otras economias de nuevo asentamiento desde 1870." Investiga-
ciones en Historia Econ6mica, 3: 135-76.

-(2011). "Institutions and the Historical Roots of Latin American Divergence", in
J. A. Ocampo and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Latin American Economics.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, ch. 2.

-(forthcoming). "Relative performance, structural change and technological capabilities
in Latin America in historical perspective," in L. Punzo, C. A. Feijo, and M. Puchet Anyul
(eds), Beyond the Global Crisis: Structural Adjustments and Regional Integration in
Europe and Latin America. Routledge Studies in the Modern World Economy. London:
Routledge.

-Bianchi, C., Cimoli, M., and Porcile, G. (2009). "Relative Performance, Structural
Change and Technological Capabilities in Latin America in Historical Perspective."
Paper presented at the XVth World Economic History Congress, Utrecht, 3-7 August.

-Camou, M., Maubrigades, S., and Melgar, N. (2010). "Human Development and
Inequality in the Twentieth Century: The Mercosur Countries in a Comparative Per-
spective," in R. D. Salvatore, J.D. Coatsworth, and A. E. ChallU (eds), Living Standards in
Latin American History: Height, Welfare and Devel(Jpment, 1750-2000. Cambridge,
Mass.: David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies, Harvard University,
197-232.

-Castelnovo, C., Rodriguez Weber, J., and Willebald, H. (2010). "Between the colonial
heritage and the first globalization boom: On income inequality in the southern cone."
Revista de Historia Econ6mica-]ournal of Iberian and Latin American Economic His-
tory, 28/2: 307-41.

- e t al. (1998). El PBI uruguayo 1870-1936 y otras estimaciones. Montevideo: Universi-
dad de Ia Republica, Facultad de Ciencias Sociales.

-Hernandez, M., and Siniscalchi, S. (2011). Un fndice hist6rico de desarrollo humano de
America Latina y algunos pafses de otras regiones: metodolog(a, fuentes y bases de datos.
Serie Documento de Trabajo. Montevideo: Facultad de Ciencias Sociales, Programa de
Historia Econ6mica y Social.

-and Porcile, G. (2006). "Convergence, Trade and Industrial Policy: Argentina, Brazil
and Uruguay in the International Economy, 1900-1980." Revista de Historia Econ6mica-
]ournal of Iberian and Latin American Economic History, 1: 37-67.

-and Williamson, J. G. (2006). "Globalization in Latin America before 1940," in
V. Bulmer-Thomas, J. H. Coatsworth, and R. Cortes Conde (eds), The Cambridge
Economic History of Latin America, vol. 2. New York: Cambridge University Press,
11-56.

References 271

Bielschowsky, R. (1998). "Cincuenta aftos de pensamiento de la CEPAL: Una resefta," in
Cincuenta afios de pensamiento de Ia CEPAL, vol. l. Santiago de Chile: Fonda de Cultura
Economica; ECLAC, 9-62.

-(2009). "Sixty Years ofECLAC: Structuralism and Neo-structuralism." CEPAL Review,
97: 173-94.

Birdsall, N., de Ia Torre, A., and Valencia Caicedo, F. (2011). "The Washington Consensus:
Assessing a 'Damaged Brand'," in J. A. Ocampo and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook
of Latin American Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 79-107 (ch. 4).

Bonilla, H. (1974). Guano y Burgues(a en Peru. Peru Problema, no. 11. Lima: Instituto de
Estudios Peruanas.

Braude!, F. (1986). La Dindmica del Capitalismo. Mexico D.F.: Fonda de Cultura
Economica.

Bulmer-Thomas, V. (1987). The Political Economy of Central America since 1920. Cam-
bridge, Mass.: Cambridge University Press.

-(2003/1994). The Economic History of Latin America since Independence, 2nd edn.
Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge University Press.

Canales, A. (2011). "Latin America in the Recent Wave of International Migration," in
J. A. Ocampo and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook ofLatin American Economics. New
York: Oxford University Press, 488-515 (ch. 20).

Cardenas, E. (1997). "A Macro-economic Interpretation of Nineteenth Century Mexico," in
S. Haber (ed.), How Latin America Fell Behind. Palo Altol CA: Stanford University Press,
65-92.

- (2000). "The Process of Accelerated Industrialization in Mexico, 1929-1982," in
E. Clirdenas, J. A. Ocampo, and R. Thorp, (eds), An Economic History of Twentieth-
Century Latin America, vol. 3: Industrialization and the State in Latin America: The
Postwar Years. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with St Antony's College, Oxford,
176-204 (ch. 7).

-(2003). Cudndo se origin6 el atraso econ6mico de Mexico: La economfa mexicana en el
largo siglo XIX, 1780-1920. Madrid: Fundacion Jose Ortega y Gasset, Editorial Biblioteca
Nueva.

-Ocampo, J. A., and Thorp, R. (2000a). An Economic History of Twentieth-Century
Latin America, vol. 3: The Export Age: The Latin American Economies in the Late
Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Centuries. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with
St Antony's College, Oxford.

--(2000b). An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 2: Indus-
trialization and the State in Latin America: The Postwar Years. Houndmills: Palgrave, in
association with St Antony's College, Oxford.

Cardoso, C. F. S. and Perez Brignoli, H. (1979). Historia Econ6mica de America Latina, vols.
1-2. Barcelona: Critica.

Cardoso, F. H. and Faletto, E. (1971). Dependencia y desarrollo en America Latina. Ciudad
de Mexico: Siglo XXI.

Carmagnani, M. (1998). "Finanzas y Estado en Mexico 1820-1880," in L. Jauregui and
J. A. Serrano (eds), Las finanzas publicas en los siglos XVIII-XIX. Mexico D.F.: Instituto
Mora; El Colegio de Michoacan; El Colegio de Mexico; Instituto de investigaciones

Historicas (UNAM).
Castro, A. B. de (1985). "Ajustamento x Transformayao: A Economia Brasileria de 1974 a

1984," in A. B. de Castro and F. E. P. de Souza (eds), A Economia Brasi/iera em Marcha
Forr,:ada. Sao Paulo: Paz e Terra, 11-98 (ch. 1).
CELADE (Centro Latinoamericano y Caribefto de Demografia/Division de Poblacion de la
CEPAL) (2006). America Latina y el Caribe: Observatorio Demografico, No.2. Santiago
de Chile: ECLAC.

272 References

CELADE and Inter-American Development Bank (1996). Impacto de las tendencias demo-
grtificas sobre los sectores sociales en America Latina: Contribucion al disefio de polfticas
y programas. Santiago de Chile: ECLAC.

Chenery, H. (1979). Structural Change and Development Policy. New York: Oxford Univer-
sity Press.

Chocano, M., Contreras, C., Quiroz, F., Mazzeo, C., and Flores, R. (2010). Economfa del
Perfodo Colonial Tardfo. Compendia de Historia del Peru, 3. Lima: IEP.

Chonchol, J. (1994). Sistemas agrarios en America Latina: De Ia etapa prehispanica a Ia
modernizacion conservadora. Mexico D.F.: Fondo de Cultura Econ6mica.

Cimoli, M. and PorcHe, G. (2011). "Learning, Technological Capabilities and Structural
Dynamics," in J. A. Ocampo and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Latin American
Economics. New York: Oxford University Press, 546-67 (ch. 22).

Cline, William R. (1984). International Debt: Systemic Risk and Policy Response. Washing-
ton, DC: Institute oflnternational Economics.

Coatsworth, J. H. (1989). "The decline of the Mexican economy, 1800-1860," in R. Liher
(ed.), America Latina en Ia Epoca de Simon Bolivar. Berlin: Colloquium Verlag, 27-53.

-(1998). "Economic and Institutional Trajectories in Nineteenth-Century Latin Amer-
ica," in J. Coatsworth and A. Taylor (eds), Latin America and the World Economy Since
1800. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University, David Rockefeller Center for Latin Ameri-
can Studies, 23-54.

-(2008). "Inequality, Institutions and Economic Growth in Latin America." Journal of
Latin American Studies, 40: 545-69.

-and Williamson, J. (2004). "Always Protectionist? Latin American Tariffs from Inde-
pendence to Great Depression." Journal of Latin American Studies, 36/2: 205-32.

Cominetti, R. and Ruiz, G. (1998). Evolucion del gasto publico social en America Latina:
1980-1995. Cuadernos de Ia CEPAL, 80. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.

Contreras, C. (2004). El Aprendizaje del Capitalismo: Estudios de historia econ6mica y social
del Peru Republicano. Lima: Instituto de Estudios Peruanas.

-and Cueto, M. (2004). Historia del Peru Contemporaneo. Lima: Instituto de Estudios
Peruanas.

Cornia, G. A. (2010). "Income Distribution under Latin America's Center-Left Regimes."
Journal of Human Development and Capabilities, 11/1: 85-114.

Cortes-Conde, R. (1997). La economfa argentina en ellargo plazo. Buenos Aires: Sudamer-
icana; Universidad de San Andres.

-and Harriague, M. (1996). Estimaciones del producto inferno de Ia Argentina. Doc-
umento de Trabajo. Buenos Aires: Universidad de San Andres, Departamento de
Economia.

Daude, Christian and Fermindez-Arias, Eduardo (2010). "Productivity and Factor Accu-
mulation in Latin America and the Caribbean: A Database." Washington, DC: Research
Department, Inter-American Development Bank. Available at: <http://www.iadb.org/
Research/pub_desc.cfm ?pub_id=D BA -0 15>.

Deas, M. (2011). "Insecurity and Economic Development in Colombia in the First Century
of Independence." Revista de Historia Econ6mica-fournal of Iberian and Latin Ameri-
can Economic History, 29/2.

De Ferranti, D., Perry, G., Ferreira, F., and Walton, M. (eds) (2004). Inequality in Latin
America and the Caribbean: Breaking with History? Washington, DC: World Bank.

De Janvry, A. (1981). The Agrarian Question and Reformism in Latin America. Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins University Press.

Delfim Netto, A. (1979). 0 problema do cafe no Brasil. Rio de Janeiro: Funda~ao Getulio
Vargas.

Della Paolera, G. and Taylor, A. (1998). "Finance and Development in an Emerging
Market: Argentina in the Interwar Period," in J. H. Coatsworth and A. M. Taylor

References 273

(1998), Latin America and the World Economy Since 1800. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard
University, David Rockefeller Center for Latin American Studies, ch. 5.
Devlin, R. (1989). Debt qnd Crisis in Latin America: The Supply Side of the Story. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.
Dl John, J. (2009). From Windfall to Curse? Oil and Industrialization in Venezuela: 1920 to
the Present. Philadelphia: Pennsylvania University Press.
Diaz, J., Liiders, R., and Wagner, G. (2007). Economfa Chilena 1810-2000: Producto total
y sectorial, una nueva mirada. Documento de Trabajo, 315. Santiago de Chile: Pontificia
Universidad Cat6lica de Chile, Instituto de Economla.
Diaz-Aiejandro, C. F. (1988). "Latin American Debt: I Don't Think we are in Kansas
Anymore," in A. Velasco (ed.), Trade, Development and the World Economy: Selected
Essays of Carlos Dfaz-Alejandro. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
-(2000). "Latin America in the 1930s," in R. Thorp (ed.), An Economic History of
Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 2: Latin America in the 1930s: The Role of the
Periphery in the World Crisis. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with St Antony's
College, Oxford, 15-42 (ch. 2).
Dosman, E. J. (2008). The Life and Times of Raul Prebisch, 1901-1986. Montreal and
Kingston: McGill-Queens' University Press.
Drake, P. W. (1989). The Money Doctor in the Andes: The Kemmerer Missions, 1923-1933.
Durham, NC: Duke University Press.
Duncan, K. and Rutledge, I. (1977). Land and Labour in Latin America: Essays on the
Development of Agrarian Capitalism in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries. Cam-
bridge: Cambridge University Press.
Dye, A. (2006). "The Institutional Framework," in V. Bulmer-Thomas, J. H. Coatsworth,
and R. Cortes Conde (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of Latin America, vol. 2.
New York: Cambridge University Press, 169-208.
Easterly, W. and Serven, L. (eds) (2003). The Limits of Stabilization: Infrastructure, Public
Deficits, and Growth in Latin America. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
ECLAC (1964). El financiamiento externo de America Latina, New York: United Nations.
-(1976). America Latina: Relacion de precios de intercambio. Cuadernos Estadisticos, l.
Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
-(1983). Industrializacion en Centroamerica 1960-1980. Estudios e Informes, 30. San-
tiago de Chile: CEPAL.
--(1990). Changing Production Patterns with Social Equity: The Prime Task of Latin
American and Caribbean Development in the 1990s. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
- (1992). El comercio de manufacturas de America Latina: Evolucion y estructura
1962-1989. Estudios e Informes, 88. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
-(1994). Open Regionalism in Latin America and the Caribbean: Economic Integration
as a Contribution to Changing Productions Pattern with Social Equity. Santiago de Chile:
United Nations.
-(1996). The Economic Experience of the Last Fifteen Years: Latin America and the
Caribbean, 1980-1995. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
-(1997). The Equity Gap: Latin America, the Caribbean and the Social Summit. Santiago
de Chile: United Nations.
-(1998). Latin America Economic Outlook. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
-(2000). Equidad, desarrollo y ciudadanfa. Bogota: ECLAC; Alfaomega.
-(2001a). A Decade ofLight and Shadow: Latin America and the Caribbean in the 1990s.
Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
-(2001b). Social Panorama of Latin America, 2000-2001. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.
-(2004). Productive Development in Open Economies. Santiago de Chile: United
Nations.

274 References

ECLAC (2006a). Shaping the Future of Social Protection: Access, Financing and Solidarity.
Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.

- (2006b). "Matriz de origen y destino de los migrantes," Supplement to the Observatorio
Demografico, 1. Santiago de Chile: CELADE-CEPAL.

- (2007a). Progreso tecnico y cambia estructural en America Latina. Santiago: ECLAC
and IDRC.

-(2007b). Latin America and the Caribbean in the World Economy. Santiago de Chile:
CEPAL.

-(2008). The Productive Transformation 20 Years After: Old Problems, New Opportun-
ities. Santiago de Chile: United Nations.

- (2009). America Latina y el Cqribe: Series hist6ricas de estadfsticas econ6micas
1950-2008. Cuadernos Estadisticos, 37. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.

-(2010). Time for Equality: Closing Gaps, Opening Trails. Santiago de Chile: United
Nations.

-and FAO (1978). 25 afios en Ia agricultura de America Latina: Rasgos principales
1950-1975. Cuadernos de la CEPAL, 21. Santiago de Chile: CEPAL.

Edwards, S. (1995). Crisis and Reform in Latin America: From Despair to Hope. New York:
Oxford University Press; Washington, DC: World Bank.

Eichengreen, B. and Fortes, R. (1989). "After the Deluge: Default, Negotiation, and Re-
adjustment during the Interwar Years," in B. Eichengreen and P. H. Lindert (eds), The
International Debt Crisis in Historical Perspective. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, ch. 2.

Eltis, D., Lewis, F. D., and Sokoloff, K. L. (eds) (2009). Human Capital and Institutions:
A Long Run View. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Engerman, S. L., Mariscal, E. V., and Sokoloff, K. L. (2009). "The Evolution of Schooling in
the Americas, 1800-1925", in D. Eltis, F. D. Lewis, and K. L. Sokoloff, Human Capital
and Institutions: The Long-Run View. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University
Press.

-and Sokoloff, K. (1997). "Factor Endowments, Institutions and Differential Paths of
Growth Among New World Economies: A View from Economic Historians of the
United States," inS. Haber (ed.), How Latin America Fell Behind. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford
University Press.

--(2001). "The Evolution of Suffrage in the New World: A Preliminary Examin-
ation." Cliometrics Society Meeting, Tucson, AZ, May 18-20, 2001.

Erten, B. and Ocampo, J, A. (2012). "Supercycles of Commodity Prices since the Mid-
nineteenth Century." DESA Working Paper, 110 (February). United Nations, Depart-
ment of Economic and Social Affairs.

Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Cambridge: Polity
Press.

Evans, P. (1995). Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton,
NJ: Princeton University Press.

Fajnzylber, F. (1983). La Industrializaci6n Trunca de America Latina. Mexico D.P.: Nueva
Imagen.

Fanelli, J. M. (ed.) (2008). Macroeconomic Volatility, Institutions and Financial Architec-
tures. The Developing World Experience. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

Feenstra, R. C. and Lipsey, M. W. (2005). "NBER-United Nations Trade Data 1962-2000."
Available at: <http://cid.econ.ucdavis.edu/data/undata/undata.html>.

Ferreira, F. H. G. and Robalino, D. (2011). "Social Protection in Latin America: Achieve-
ments and Limitations," in J, A. Ocampo and J, Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook ofLatin
American Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 836-62 (ch. 33).

Ferrer, A. (2010). La Econom(a Argentina: Desde sus or{genes hasta principios del Siglo XXI.
Mexico D.P.: Fondo de Cultura Econ6mica.

References 275

Ffrench-Davis, R. (2005). Reformas para America Latina: despues del fundamentalismo
neoliberal. Buenos Aires: Siglo XXI.

-Munoz, 0., and Palma, G. (1998). "The Latin American Economies, 1959-1990," in
L. Bethell (ed.), The Cambridge History ofLatin America, vol. 6: Latin America: Economy
and Society Since 1930. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Filgueira, F. (1997). "Tipos de welfare y reformas sociales en America Latina: Eficiencia,
residualismo y ciudadania estratificada." Paper prepared for the project "Social Policy
and Social Citizenship in Central America." Guadalajara: Social Science Research

Council.
-Molina, C. G., Papadopulos, J, and Tobar, F. (2006). "Universalismo basico: una

alternativa posible y necesaria para mejorar las condiciones de vida," in C. G. Molina
(ed.), Universalismo basico: Una nueva polftica social para America Latina. Washington,
DC: Inter"American Development Bank; Planeta, ch. 1.
Findlay, R. and O'Rourke, K. H. (2007). Power and Plenty: Trade, War, and the World
Economy in the Second Millennium. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Fishlow, A. (1988). "The State of Latin American Economics," in Christopher Mitchell
(ed.), Changing Perspectives in Latin American Studies: Insights from Six Disciplines. Palo
Alto, CA: Stanford University Press, 87-119 (ch. 3).
FitzGerald, E. V. K. (1978). "The Fiscal Crisis of the Latin American State," in J. F. J. Toye
(ed.), Taxation and Economic Development. London: Frank Cass, 125-58.
Fogel, R. W. (2009). Escapar del Hambre y Ia Muerte Prematura. Madrid: Alianza.
Folchi, M. and Rubio, M. (2006). "El consumo de energia f6sil y la especificidad de Ia
transici6n energetica en America Latina, 1900-1930." Paper presented at the III Simpo-
sio Latinoamericano y Caribeiio de Historia Ambiental, Carmona, April.
Frankema, E. (2009). Has Latin America Always Been Unequal? A Comparative Study of
Asset and Income Inequality in the Long Twentieth Century. Leiden and Boston: Brill.
Frenkel, R. and Rapetti, M. (2011). "Exchange Rate Regimes in Latin America," in
J. A. Ocampo and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Latin American Economics.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, ch. 8.
-and Rozenwurcel, G. (1990). "Restricci6n externa y generaci6n de recursos para el
crecimiento en la America Latina." El Tritnestre Econ6mico, 225: 983-1014.
Furtado, C. (1976). Economic Development ofLatin America: A Survey from Colonial Times
to the Cuban Revolution, 2nd edn. Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge University Press.
-(1989). La fantasia organizada. Bogota: Tercer Mundo.
Gallagher, K. P. and Porzecanski, R. (2010). The Dragon in the Room: China and the Future
of Latin American Industrialization. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
Ganuza, E., Paes de Barros, R., and Vos, R. (eds) (2002). "Labour Market Adjustment,
Poverty and Inequality during Liberalization," in Economic Liberalization, Distribution
and Poverty. Cheltenham (UK): Edward Elgar Publishing, 54-81.
Garda, N. (2007). "Empleo y Globalizaci6n en America Latina." Revista de Econom{a
Mundia/, 17: 51-75.
-and Tokman, V. (1984). "Changes in Employment and the Crisis." CEPAL Review, 24:
103-15.
Gasparini, L., Cruces, G., and Tornarolli, L. (2011). "Recent Trends in Income Inequality in
Latin America." Economia, 10 (Spring): 147-201.
- - - a n d Marchionni, M. (2009). A Turning Point? Recent Developments on
Inequality in Latin America and the Caribbean. New York: RBLAC-PNUD (Research
for Public Policy, Human Development, HD-02-2009).
-and Lustig, N. (2011). "The Rise and Fall oflncome Inequality in Latin America," in
J. A. Ocampo and J, Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Latin American Economics.
Oxford: Oxford University Press, 691-714 (ch. 27).

276 References

Gelman, J. (2009). "tCrisis postcolonial en las economias sudamericanas?," in E. Llopis and
C. Marichal (ed.), Latinoamerica y Espana, 1800-1850: Un crecimiento econ6mico nada
excepcional. Madrid: Marcial Pons, 25-64.

-(2011). "Dimension econ6mica de la independencia," in Las Indepedencias latino-
americanas y el persistente sueno de Ia Gran Patria Nuestra. Mexico D.P.: Servicio de
Relaciones Exteriores de la Cancilleria Mexicana.

-and Santilli, D. (2010). "Crecimiento econ6mico, divergencia regional y distribucion de
la riqueza. Cordoba y Buenos Aires despues de la independencia." Latin American
Research Review, 45/1: 121-47.

Gerchunoff, P. and Llach, L. (1998). El ciclo de Ia ilusi6n y el desencanto: Un siglo de polfticas
econ6micas argentinas. Buenos Aires: Ariel Sociedad Economica.

Gerschenkron, A. (1962). Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Cambridge,
Mass.: Harvard University Press.

Glade, W. (1986). "Latin America and the International Economy, 1870-1914," in
L. Bethell (ed.), The Cambridge History of Latin America, vol. 4: c.1870 to 1930.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, ch. 1.

Goldsmith, R. W. (1986). Brasil 1850-1984: Desenvolvimento financiero sob un seculo de
inflafaO. Sao Paulo: Harper & Row do Brasil.

-(1973). A Century of Financial Development in Latin America. Economic Growth
Center Paper, 196. New Haven, CT: Yale University.

Gootenberg, P. (1989). Between Silver and Guano: Commercial Policy and the State in
Postindependence Peru. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Greasley, D., Madsen, J, B., and Oxley, L. (2000). "Real Wages in Australia and Canada,
1870-1913: Globalization versus Productivity." Australian Economic History Review, 2:
178-98.

Haber, S. (1989). Industry and Underdevelopment: The Industrialization of Mexico,
1890-1940. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.

-(2010). "Mercado interno, industrializaci6n y banca, 1890-1929," inS. Kuntz Ficker
(ed.), Historia econ6mica general de Mexico: De Ia Colonia a nuestros dfas. Mexico D.P.:
El Colegio de Mexico y Secretaria de Economia, ch. 9.

-(2006). "The Political Economy of Industrialization," in V. Bulmer-Thomas,
J, H. Coatsworth, and R. Cortes Conde (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of
Latin America, vol. 2. New York: Cambridge University Press, 537-84.

Haddad, C. L. S. (1980). "Crecimiento economico do Brasil, 1900-76," in P. Neuhaus (ed.),
Economia Brasileira: Uma Visao Hist6rica. Rio de Janeiro: Campus.

Haggard, S. and Kaufman, R. R. (2008). Development, Democracy, and Welfare States: Latin
America, East Asia, and Eastern Europe. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Halperin Donghi, T. (2008/1969). Historia contemporanea de America Latina. Madrid:
Alianza.

Hanushek, E. A. and Woessmann, L. (2009). "Do Better Schools Lead to More Growth?
Cognitive Skills, Economic Outcomes, and Causation." NBER Working Paper, 14633.

Hatton, T. J. and Williamson, J. G. {1994). "International Migration, 1850-1939: An
Economic Survey," in T. J, Hatton and J. G. Williamson (eds), Migration and the
International Labour Market, 1850-1939. London: Routledge, 3-34.

--(2005). Global Migration and the World Economy: Two Centuries of Policy and
Performance. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Hausmann, R. (2011). "Structural Transformation and Economic Growth in Latin Amer-
ica," in J. A. Ocampo and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Latin American
Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 519-45 (ch. 21).

-Hwang, J., and Rodrik, D. (2007). "What You Export Matters." Journal of Economic
Growth, 12/1: 1-25.

References 277

Helleiner, E. (2009). "The Development Mandate of International Institutions: Where Did
They Come From." Studies of International Comparative Development. Dol 10.1007/

s12116-009-9042-3.
Hirschman, A. 0. (1971). "The Political Economy oflmport-Substituting Industrialization

in Latin America," in id., A Bias for Hope: Essays on Development and Latin America.
New Haven, CT: Yale University Press, ch. 3.
-(1987). "The Political Economy of Latin American Development: Seven Exercises in
Retrospection." Latin American Research Review, 22/3: 7-36.
Hofman, A. (2000). The Economic Development ofLatin America in the Twentieth Century.

Cheltenham (UK): Edward Elgar Publishing.
Holloway, T. (1977). "The Coffee Colona of Sao Paulo, Brazil: Migration and Mobility,

1880-1930," in K. Duncan and I. Rutledge, Land and Labour in Latin America. Essays on
the Development of Agrarian Capitalism in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 301-21.
Hunt, S. J, (1985). "Growth and Guano in Nineteenth Century Peru," in R. Cortes Conde and
S. J. Hunt (eds), The Latin American Economies: Growth and the Export Sector 1880-1930.
New York: Holmes & Meier.
IDB (Inter-American Development Bank) (1997). Latin America After a Decade ofReforms.
Economic and Social Progress in Latin America, 1997. Washington, DC: Inter-American

Development Bank.
-(1999). Facing Up to Inequality in Latin America. Economic and Social Progress in

Latin America, 1998-1999. Washington, DC: Inter-American Development Bank.
-(2008a). Beyond Facts, Understanding Quality of Life, ed. E. Lora. Washington, DC:

Inter-American Development Bank; Harvard University: David Rockefeller Center for

Latin American Studies.
-(2008b). All That Glitters May Not Be Gold: Assessing Latin America's Recent Macro-

economic Performance, ed. A. Izquierdo and E. Talvi. Washington, DC: Inter-American

Development Bank.
-(2010). The Age of Productivity: Transforming Economies from the Bottom Up, ed.

C. Pages. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Irigoin, A. (2009). "Gresham on Horseback: The Monetary Roots of Spanish American

Political Fragmentation in the Nineteenth Century." Economic History Review, 62/3:

551-75.
Jauregui, L. and Marichal, C. (2009). "Paradojas fiscales y financieras de la temprana

republica mexicana, 1825-1855," in E. Llopis and C. Marichal (eds), Latinoamerica y
Espana, 1800-1850: Un crecimiento econ6mico nada excepcional. Madrid and Mexico,
D.P.: Marcial Pons, Ediciones de Historia; Instituto Mora, 111-60.
-and Serrano, J. A. (1998). "Introducci6n," in L. Jauregui and J. A. Serrano (eds), Las
finanzas publicas en los siglos XVIII-XIX. Mexico D.P.: Instituto Mora, El Colegio de
Michoacan; El Colegio de Mexico, UNAM-Instituto de Investigaciones Hist6ricas.
Jorgensen, E. and Sachs, J. (1989). "Default and Renegotiation of Latin American Foreign
Bonds in the Interwar Period," in B. Eichengreen and P. H. Lindert (eds), The Inter-
national Debt Crisis in Historical Perspective. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, ch. 3.
Jorgensen, S. L. and Paldam, M. (1987). "The Real Exchange Rates of Eight Latin American
Countries 1946-1985: An Interpretation." Geld und Wiirung, 3/4: 5-27.
Kalmanovitz, S. (ed.) (1994). Economia y Naci6n: una breve historia de Colombia, 2nd edn.
Bogota: Universidad Nacional; Tercer Mundo Editores.
Kalmanovitz, S. (2010). Nueva historia econ6mica de Colombia. Bogota: Taurus and Uni-

versidad Jorge Tadeo Lozano.
-and Lopez Rivera, E. (2009). Las Cuentas Nacionales de Colombia en el Siglo XIX.

Bogota: Universidad de Bogota Jorge Tadeo Lozano.

278 References

Kaminsky, G. L., Reinhart, C. M., and Vegh, C. A. (2004). "When It Rains, It Pours:
Procyclical Capital Flows and Macroecnomic Policies." NBER Macroeconomics Annual,
19: 11-53.

Katz, J. (1978). "Creaci6n de tecnologla en el sector manufacturero argentino." Trimestre
Econ6mico, 177: 167-90.

-(1984). "Domestic Technological Innovations and Comparative Advantage: Further
Reflections on a Comparative Case-study Program." Journal ofDevelopment Economics,
16/1-2: 13-37.

-and Kosacoff, B. (2000). "Technological Learning, Institution Building and the Micro-
economics of Import Substitutions," in E. Cardenas, J. A. Ocampo, and R. Thorp (eds),
An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 3: Industrialization and
the State in Latin America: The Postwar Years. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with
St Antony's College, Oxford, 36-57 (ch. 2).

Kindleberger, C. P. and Aliber, R. (2005). Manias, Panics, and Crashes: A History of
Financial Crises, 5th edn. New Jersey: John Wiley & Sons.

Klaren, P. (1977). "The Peruvian Sugar Industry, 1870-1930," in K. Duncan and
I. Rutledge, Land and Labour in Latin America: Essays on the Development of Agrarian
Capitalism in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-
sity Press.

Klein, H. S. and Vinson Ill, B. (2007). African Slavery in Latin America and the Caribbean.
2nd edn. New York: Oxford University Press.

Kuczynski, P.P. and Williamson, J. (eds) (2003). After the Washington Consensus: restarting
growth and reform in Latin America. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International
Economics.

Kuntz-Ficker, S. (2010). Las exportaciones mexicanas durante Ia primera globalizaci6n
1870-1929. Mexico D.F.: El Colegio de Mexico, Centro de Estudios Hist6ricos.

La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., and Shleifer, A. (2002). "Government Ownership of
Banks." Journal of Finance, 57/1: 265-301.

Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2008). Systemic Banking Crises: A New Database. IMF Working
Paper, 08/224. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

Lall, S. (2001). Competitiveness, Technology and Skins. Cheltenham (UK): Edward Elgar
Publishing.

Landes, D. (1999). The Wealth and Poverty ofNations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So
Poor. New York: W.W. Norton & Company.

Leff, N.H. (1997). "Economic Development in Brazil, 1822-1913," inS. Haber (ed.), How
Latin America Fell Behind. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press, 34-64.

- (1982). Underdevelopment and Development in Brazil, vol. I: Economic Structure and
Change, 1822-1947. London: George Allen and Unwin.

Levitsky, S. and Roberts, K. M. (eds) (2011). The Resurgence of the Left in Latin America.

Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Levy, S. (2008). Good Intentions, Bad Outcomes: Social Policy, Informality, and Economic

Growth in Mexico. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
Lewis, C. (1991). "La industria antes de 1930," in L. Bethell (ed.), Historia de America

Latina, vol. 7: Economfa y sociedad, c.1870-1930. Barcelona: Crltica, 231-80.
Lewis, W. A. (1952). "World Production, Prices and Trade, 1870-1960." Manchester School

of Economic and Social Studies, 20: 105-34.
-(1954). "Economic Development with Unlimited Supplies of Labour." Manchester

School of Economic and Social Studies, 22/2: 139-91.
-(1969). Aspects of Tropical Trade, 1883-1965. Serie Wicksell Lectures. Stockholm:

Almqvist & Wiksell.
-(1978). Growth and Fluctuations, 1870-1913. London: George Allen and Unwin.

References 279

Lindert, P. (2004). Growing Public. Social Spending and Economic Growth Since the
Eighteenth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

-(2010). "The Unequal Lag in Latin American Schooling since 1900: Follow the
Money." Revista de Historia Econ6mica-Journal of Iberian and Latin American Eco-
nomic History, 28/2: 375-405.

Llopis, E. and Marichal, C. (ed.) (2009). Latinoamerica y Espana, 1800-1850: Un creci-
miento econ6mico nada excepcional. Madrid; Mexico, D.F.: Marcial Pons, Ediciones de

Historia; Instituto Mora.
Londono, J. L. and Szekely, M. (2000). "Persistent Poverty and Excess Inequality: Latin

America, 1970-1995." Journal of Applied Economics, 3/1: 93-134.
L6pez-Calva, L. F. and Lustig, N. (eds) (2010). Declining Inequality in Latin America:

A Decade of Progress. New York and Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press;

UNDP.
Lora, E. (2001). Structural Reforms in Latin America: What Has Been Reformed and How to

Measure It. Research Department Working Paper, WP 466. Washington, DC: Inter-

American Development Bank.
-(2011). "The Effects of Trade Liberalization on Growth and Employment," in

J. A. Ocampo and J, Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Latin American Economics.

Oxford: Oxford University Press, 368-93 (ch. 15).
Love, J. L. (1994). "Economic Ideas and Ideologies in Latin America Since 1930," in

L. Bethell (ed.), The Cambridge History ofLatin America, vol. 6: Latin America: Economy
and Society Since 1930. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lynch, J. (1992). Caudillos in Spanish America, 1800-1850. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Maddison, A. (1995). Monitoring the World Economy, 1820-1992. Paris: OECD Develop-

ment Centre.
-(2001). The World Economy: A Millennia/ Perspective. Paris: OECD Development

Centre.
-(2007). Contours of the World Economy, 1-2030 AD: Essays in Macro-Economic

History. New York: Oxford University Press.
-(2008). "The West and the Rest in the World Economy: 1000-2030: Maddisonian and

Malthusian Interpretations." World Economics, 9/4: 75-100.
Manzel, K. and Baten, J, (2009). "Gender Equality and Inequality inNumeracy: The Case of

Latin America and the Caribbean, 1880-1949." Revista de Historia Econ6mica, 27/1:

37-73.
Marichal, C. (1989). A Century of Debt Crisis in Latin America: From Independence to the

Great Depression, 1820-1930. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Martinez Pizarro, J. (2011). Migraci6n internacional en America Latina: Nuevas tendencias,

nuevas enfoques. Santiago de Chile: ECLAC.
Matus, M. (2009). Precios y Salarios Reales en Chile durante el Cicio Salitrero, 1880-1930.

PhD thesis. Barcelona: Universldad de Barcelona, Programa Interuniversitario de His-

toria Econ6mica.
Mesa-Lago, C. (1978). Social Security in Latin America: Pressure Groups, Stratification, and

Inequality. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.
-(1981). The Economy of Socialist Cuba: A Two-Decade Appraisal. Albuquerque, NM:

University of New Mexico Press.
Meyer, J. W., Ramirez, F. 0., and Soysal, Y. N. (1992). "World Expansion of Mass

Education, 1870-1980." Sociology of Education, 65/2 (April): 128-49.
Mitchell, B. R. (2003). International Historical Statistics: The Americas, 1750-1993. London

and New York: Macmillan Reference; Stockton Press.
-with Deane, P. (1962). Abstract of British Historical Statistics. Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.
Mitre, A. (1993). Baja un cielo de estafio. La Paz: Biblioteca Minera Boliviana.

280 References

Mokyr, J. (2002). The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Society. Prince-
ton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Moreno-Brid, J. C. and Ros, J. (2009). Development and Growth in the Mexican Economy:
A Historical Perspective. New York: Oxford University Press.

Moreno Fraginals, M. (1978). El ingenio: complejo economico social cubano del azucar. La
Habana: Editorial de Ciencias Sociales.

-(1991). "Economias y sociedades de plantaci6n en el Caribe espaii.ol, 1860-1930," in
L. Bethell (ed.), Historia de America Latina, vol. 7: Economfa y sociedad, c.1870-1930.
Barcelona: Critica, 163-201.

Morley, S. (1995). Poverty and Inequality in Latin America: The Impact ofAdjustment and
Recovery in the 1980s. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins l)niversity Press.

-(2000). La distribucion de ingreso in America Latina y el Caribe. Santiago de Chile:
Fonda de Cultura Econ6mica; ECLAC.

-Machado, R., and Pettinato, S. (1999). "Indexes of Structural Reform in Latin America."
Serie Reformas Econ6micas, No. 12. Santiago de Chile: ECLAC.

Morner, M. (1977). '"Landlords' and 'Peasants', and the Outer World," inK. Duncan and
I. Rutledge (eds), Land and Labour in Latin America: Essays on the Development of
Agrarian Capitalism in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.

Morrisson, C. and Murtin, F. (2008). "The Century of Education." journal of Human
Capital, 3/1: 1-42

.Murillo, M. V., Ronconi, L., and Schrank, A. (2011). "Latin American Labor Reforms:
Evaluating Risk and Security," in J, A. Ocampo and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of
Latin American Economics. New York: Oxford University Press, 790-812 (ch. 31).

Newsom, L. (2006). "The Demographic Impact of Colonization", in V. Bulmer-Thomas,
J, Coatsworth, and R. Cortes Conde (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of Latin
America, vol. 1. New York: Cambridge University Press, 143-1836.

North, D., Summerhill, W., and Weingast, B. R. (2000). "Order, Disorder and Economic
Change: Latin America versus North America," in F. Mesquita and F. R. Root (eds),
Governing for Prosperity. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

North, D., Wallis, J. J., and Weingast, B. R. (2009). Violence and Social Orders: A Conceptual
Framework for Understanding Recorded Human History. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge
University Press.

Ocampo, J. A. (1984). Colombia y Ia economfa mundia/, 1830-1910. Bogota: Siglo XXI;
FEDESARROLLO.

- (1990). Comerciantes, artesanos y polftica econ6mica en Colombia, 1830-1880. Boletin
Cultural y Bibliognifico, 22. Bogota: Banco de la Republica.

-(2004a). Reconstruir el futuro: globalizacion, desarrollo y democracia en America
Latina. Bogota: Grupo Editoral Norma; ECLAC.

-(2004b). "Latin America's Growth and Equity Frustrations During Structural
Reforms." journal of Economic Perspectives, 18/2: 67-88.

-(2007). "The Macroeconomics of the Latin American Economic Boom." CEPAL
Review, 93: 7-28.

-(2008a). "Las concepciones de la politica social: universalismo versus focalizaci6n."
Nueva Sociedad, 215: 36-61.

-(2008b). "A Broad View of Macroeconomic Stability," in N. Serra and J, E. Stiglitz
(eds), The Washington Consensus Reconsidered. New York: Oxford University Press,
63-94.

-(2011). "Macroeconomy for Development: Countercyclical Policies and Production
Sector Transformation." CEPAL Review, 104, 7-35.

References 281

Ocampo, J. A. and Martin, J. (eds) (2003). Globalization and Development: A Latin
American and Caribbean Perspective. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press,

ECLAC and World Bank.
--(eds) (2004). America Latina y el Caribe en Ia era global. Bogota: ECLAC;

Alfaomega.
-and Parra, M. A. (2003). "The Terms of Trade for Commodities in the Twentieth

Century." CEPAL Review, 79: 7-35.
--(2007). "The Dual Divergence: Growth Successes and Collapses in the Developing

World Since 1980," in R. Ffrench-Davis and J. L. Machinea (eds), Economic Growth with
Equity: Challenges for Latin America. Houndmills: Palgrave Macmillan; ECLAC.
--(2010). "The Terms of Trade for Commodities since the Mid-Nineteenth
Century." Revista de Historia Economica-journal of Iberian and Latin American
Economic History, 28/1: 11-37.
-Rada, C., and Taylor, L. (2009). Growth and Policy in Developing Countries:
A Structuralist Approach. New York: Columbia University Press, ch. 1.
-and Tovar, C. (2000). "Colombia in the Classical Era of 'Inward-Looking Develop-
ment, 1930-74'," in E. Gardenas, J. A. Ocampo, and R. Thorp (eds), An Economic History
of Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 3: Industrializtltion and the State in Latin
America: The Postwar Years. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with St Antony's
College, Oxford, 239-81 (ch. 9).
-and Vos, R. (2008). Uneven Economic Development. London: Zed Books; United

Nations.
O'Connell, A. (2000). "Argentina into the Depression: Problems of an Open Economy," in

R. Thorp (ed.), An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 2: Latin
America in the 1930s: The Role of the Periphery in the World Crisis. Houndmills:
Palgrave, in association with St Antony's College, Oxford, 165-94 (ch. 8).
O'Rourke, K. H. and Williamson, J. G. (1999). "The Heckscher-Ohlin Model Between 1400
and 2000: When It Explained Factor Price Convergence, When It Did Not, and Why.''
NBER Working Paper Series, WP 7411.
--(2006). "Around the European Periphery 1870-1913: Globalization, Schooling
and Growth.'' European Review of Economic History, 1/2: 53-190.
Orihuela, J, C. (2010). Globalizations, Green Governance and Environmental Change:
Towards a Modern Environmental History of Latin America. Working Paper, Initiative
for Policy Dialogue. New York: Columbia University.
OXLAD (2011). Oxford Latin American Economic History Database. Available at: <http://

www.qeh.ox.ac.uk/centres/oxlad>.
Pages, C. (ed.) (2010). The Age of Productivity: Transforming Economies from the Bottom

Up. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Palacios, M. (1983). El Cafe en Colombia 1850-1970: Una historia economica, social y

polftica. Mexico D.P.: El Colegio de Mexico.
Palma, G. (2000). "Trying to 'Tax and Spend' Oneself out of the 'Dutch Disease': The

Chilean Economy from the War of the Pacific to the Great Depression," in E. Cardenas,

J. A. Ocampo, and R. Thorp (eds), An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin
America, vol. 3: The Export Age: The Latin American Economies in the Late Nineteenth
and Early Twentieth Centuries. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with St Antony's

College, Oxford, 217-64 (ch. 8).
-(2005). "Cuatro fuentes de 'desindustrializaci6n' y un nuevo concepto del 'sindrome

holandes'," in J. A. Ocampo (ed.), Mas alia de las reformas: Dinamica estructural y
vulnerabilidad macroeconomica. Bogota: Alfaomega; ECLAC, ch. 3.

-(2009). "Flying-Geese and Waddling-Ducks: The Different Capabilities of East Asia
and Latin America to 'Demand-Adapt' and 'Supply-Upgrade' their Export Productive

282 References

Capacity," in J, E. Stiglitz, M. Cimoli, and G. Dosi (eds), Industrial Policy in Developing
Countries. New York: Oxford University Press.
-(2011). "Why Has Productivity Growth Stagnated in Latin America Since the Neo-
Liberal Reforms?" in J. A. Ocampo and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Latin
American Economics. New York: Oxford University Press, 568-607 (ch. 23).
Pelaez, C. M. (1973). "Analises economica do programa brasileiro de sustentayao do cafe
1906-1945: teoria, politica e midoyao," in M. Moitinho, Ensaios sobre cafe e desenvolvi-
mento economico. Rio de Janeiro: Instituto Brasileiro do Cafe.
Peres, W. (2012). "Industrial Policies in Latin America," in A. Szirmai, W. Naude, and
L. Alcorta (eds), Pathways to Industrialization: New Challenges and Emerging Paradigms.
New York: Oxford University Press, ch. 7.
Polanyi, K. (1957). The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our
Time. Boston: Beacon Press.
Prados de Ia Escosura, L. (2007). "Inequality and Poverty in Latin America: A Long-Run
Exploration," in T. J, Hatton, K. H. O'Rourke, and A. M. Taylor (eds), The New
Comparative Economic History: Essays in Honor of Jeffrey G. Williamson. Cambridge,
Mass.: MIT Press, ch. 12.

- (2009). "Lost Decades? Economic Performance in Post- Independence Latin America."
Journal of Latin American Studies, 41/2: 279-307.

PREALC (1981). Dinamica del subempleo en America Latina. Santiago de Chile: ECLAC.
Prebisch, R. (1973). Interpretacion del proceso de desarrollo latinoamericano en 1949, 2nd

edn. Serie conmemorativa del XXV aniversario de Ia CEPAL. Santiago de Chile: ECLAC.
Proyecto GRECO (1999). El crecimiento econ6mico colombiano en e/ siglo XX: aspectos

globales. Bogota: Banco de Ia Republica de Colombia.
Przeworski, A. (2011). "Latin American Political Regimes in Comparative Perspective," in

P. Kingstone and D. J, Yashar (eds), Routledge Handbook of Latin American Politics.
London: Routledge.
Rapoport, M. (2000). Historia econ6mica, polftica y social de Ia Argentina (1880-2000).
Buenos Aires: Ediciones Macchi.

Reimers, F. (2006). "Education and Social Progress" in V. Bulmer-Thomas,
J. H. Coatsworth, and R. Cortes Conde (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of
Latin America, vol. 2. New York: Cambridge University Press, 427-82.

Reinhart, C. and Rogoff, K. (2009). This Time is Different: Eight Centuries ofFinancial Folly.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Robinson, J. (2006). "El equilibria de America Latina", in Fukuyama, F. (ed.) La Brecha
entre America Latina y Estados Unidos. Buenos Aires: Fondo de Cultura Econ6mica.

Rodriguez, J. L. (1990). Estrategia del desarrollo econ6mico en Cuba. La Habana: Editorial
de Ciencias Sociales.

Rodriguez, 0. (1980). La teorfa del subdesarrol/o de Ia CEPAL. Mexico D.P.: Siglo XXI.
- (2006). El estructuralismo latinoamericano. Mexico D.P.: Siglo XXI; ECLAC.
Rodriguez Weber, J. E. (2009). "Los Tiempos de Ia Desigualdad: La Distribuci6n del Ingreso

en Chile 1860-1930." MA thesis in Economic History, Facultad de Ciencias Sociales,
Universidad de Ia Republica, Uruguay.
Romero, E. (2000). Historia Econ6mica del Peru. Lima: Sudamericana.
Ros, J. (2009). "Poverty Reduction in Latin America: The Role of Demographic, Social and
Economic Factors." CEPAL Review, 98: 35-45.
Rosenthal, G. (2004). "ECLAC: A Commitment to a Latin American Way Towards
Development," in Y. Berthelot (ed.), Unity and Diversity in Development Ideas: Perspec-
tives from the UN Regional Commissions. United Nations Intellectual History Project.
Bloomington, IN: Indiana University Press.
Rowe, J, W. F. (1932). Studies in the Artificial Control of Raw Material Supplies: Brazilian
Coffee, vol. 3. London and Cambridge: Royal Economic Society.

References 283

-(1965). Primary Commodities in International Trade. Cambridge: Cambridge Univer-

sity Press.
Rowthorn, R. E. and Wells, J. (1987). De-Industrialization and Foreign Trade. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.
Rubio, M. M., Yanez, C., Folchi, M., and Carreras, A. (2010). "Energy as an Indicator of

Modernization in Latin America, 1890-1925." Economic History Review, 63/3: 769-804.
Salvucci, R. (2006). "Export-led Industrialization," in V. Bulmer-Thomas, J. H. Coatsworth,

and R. Cortes Conde (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of Latin America, vol. 2.
New York: Cambridge University Press, 249-92.
Sanchez Alborn6z, N. (1991). "La Poblaci6n, 1850-1930," in L. Bethell (ed.), Historia de
America Latina, vol. 7: Economfa y sociedad, c.1870-1930. Barcelona: Critica, 106-32.
Sanchez Alonso, B. (2006). "Labor and Immigration," in V. Bulmer-Thomas, J. Coatsworth,
and R. Cortes Conde (eds), The Cambridge Economic History of Latin America, vol. 2.
New York: Cambridge University Press, 377-426.
Sanchez Santir6, E. (2009a). Las a/cabalas mexicanas (1821-1857): los di/emas de Ia con-
strucci6n de Ia hacienda nacional. Mexico D.P.: Instituto Mora.
-(2009b). "El desempefto de Ia economia mexicana tras Ia independencia, 1821-1870:
nuevas evidencias e interpretaciones," in E. Llopis and C. Marichal (eds), Latinoamerica
y Espana, 1800-1850: Un crecimiento econ6mico nada excepcional. Madrid and Mexico,
D.P.: Marcial Pons, Ediciones de Historia; Instituto Mora, 65-110.
-(2010a). "Una modernizaci6n conservadora: el reformismo borb6nico y su impacto

sobre Ia economia, Ia fiscalidad y las instituciones," in C. Garcia Ayluardo and E. Pani
(eds), Historia crftica de las modernizaciones en Mexico, vol. 1. Mexico D.P.: CIDE,

Secretaria de Hacienda y Credito Publico.
-(2010b). "El desempefto de Ia economia mexicana, 1810-1860: de Ia Colonia al Estado-

naci6n," inS. Kuntz-Ficker (ed.), Historia econ6mica general de Mexico: de Ia Colonia a
nuestros dfas. Mexico D.P.: El Colegio de Mexico; Secretaria de Economia, ch. 9.
Santamaria, A. (2009). Las cuentas nacionales de Cuba, 1690-2009. La Habana: Instituto de
Historia; CSIC.
-(2011). "Dos siglos de especializaci6n y dos decadas de incertidumbre: La historia
econ6mica de Cuba, 1800-2010," in L. Bertola and P. Gerchunoff(eds), Institucionalidad
y Desarrollo Econ6mico en America Latina. Santiago de Chile: ECLAC and AECID, 135-

90 (ch. 5).
-and Malamud, C. (2001). Sin azucar no hay pais: La industria azucarera y Ia economfa

cubana (1919-1939). Serie Historia y Geografia, 66. Sevilla: Secretariado de Publicaciones

de Ia Universidad de Sevilla.
Santiso, J. and Zoido, P. (2011). "Fiscal Legitimacy, Inequalities and Democratic Consoli-

dation in Latin America," in J, A. Ocampo and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of
Latin American Economics. New York: Oxford University Press, 293-313 (ch. 12).
Sanz Fernandez, J. (ed.) (1998). Historia de losferrocarriles de Iberoamerica (1837-1995).

Madrid: Ministerio de Fomento.
Schvarzer, J. (1996). La Industria que supimos conseguir. Una historia poUtico-social de Ia

industria argentina. Buenos Aires: Planeta.
Scobie, J. (1991). "El crecimiento de las ciudades latinoamericanas, 1870-1930," in

L. Bethell (ed.), Historia de America Latina, vol. 7: Economfa y sociedad, c.1870-1930.
Barcelona: Critica, 202-30.
Sen, A. (1993). "Capability and Well-being," in M. Nussbaum and A. Sen (eds), The Quality
of Life. Oxford: Clarendon Press, 30-53.
Sheahan, J. (1987). Patterns of Development in Latin America: Poverty, Repression, and
Economic Strategy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.
Solbrig, 0. T. (2006). "Structure, Performance and Policy in Agriculture," in V. Bulmer-
Thomas, J. H. Coatsworth, and R. Cortes Conde (eds), The Cambridge Economic History
of Latin America, vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 483-536.

284 References

Stallings, B. (1987). Banker to the Third Word: U.S. Portfolio Investment in Latin America,
1900-1986. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.

-and Peres, W. (2000). Crecimiento, empleo y equidad: El impacto de las reformas
econ6micas en America Latina y e/ Caribe. Mexico, D.P.: Fonda de Cultura Economica;
ECLAC.

-and Weller, J, (2001). "Employment in Latin America: Cornerstone of Social Policy."
CEPAL Review, 75: 191-210.

Summerhill, W. R. (2006). "Sovereign Commitment and Financial Underdevelopment in
Imperial Brazil." Working draft prepared for the conference "States and Capital Markets
in Comparative Historical Perspective," UCLA Center for Economic History.

Sunkel, 0. (1971). "Capitalismo transnacional y desintegracion nacional en America
Latina." Estudios Internm;ionales, 4/16: 3-61.

Sunkel, 0. (ed.) (1991). El desarrollo desde dentro: un enfoque neoestructuralista para Ia
America Latina. Lecturas del Trimestre Economico, 71. Mexico D.P.: Fonda de Cultura
Economica.

Sunkel, 0. and Paz, P. (1970). Subdesarrollo /atinoamericano y Ia teoria del desarrollo.
Mexico D.P.: Siglo XXI.

Suzigan, W. (1986). Industria Brasi/eira: origem e desemvolvimento. Sao Paulo: Editora
Brasiliense.

Szekely, M. (2001). Los afios 90 en America Latina: otra decada de desigualdad persistente,
pero con un poco menos de pobreza. Documento de Trabajo, 454. Washington, DC: Inter-
American Development Bank, Departamento de Investigacion.

-and Montes, A. (2006). "Poverty and Inequality," in V. Bulmer-Thomas,
J. H. Coatsworth, and R. Cortes Conde (eds), Cambridge Economic History of Latin
America, vol. 2. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, ch. 14.

Tafunell, X. (2009a). "La inversion en equipo de transporte de America Latina, 1890-1930:
Una estilpacion basada en Ia demanda de importaciones." Investigaciones de Historia
Econ6mica, 14: 39-67.

-(2009b). "Capital Formation in Machinery in Latin America, 1890-1930." Journal of
Economic History, 69/4: 928-50.

Taussig, M. (1977). "The Evolution of Rural Wage Labour in the Cauca Valley of Colombia,
1700-1970," inK. Duncan and I. Rutledge, Land and Labour in Latin America. Essays on
the Development of Agrarian Capitalism in the Nineteenth and Twentieth Centuries.
Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Teitel, S. (1993). Industrial and Technological Development. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press; Inter-American Development Bank.

-and Thoumi, F. E. (1987). "De Ia sustitucion de importaciones a las exportaciones
manufactureras de la Argentina y el Brasil." Desarrollo Econ6mico, 27/105: 29-60.

Tello, C. (2008). Estado y desarrollo econ6mico: Mexico 1920-2006. Mexico D.P.: Universi-
dad Nacional Autonoma de Mexico, Facultad de Economia.

Tena-Junguito, A. and Federico, G. (2011). "What Do We Know about the International
Export Performance of the Americas between 1820 and 1940?" Paper presented at the
lOth Congreso Internacional de Ia AEHE, 8-10 September, Universidad Pablo de
Olavide, Carmona (Spain).

Thorp, R. (1986). "Latin America and the International Economy from the First World
War to the World Depression," in L. Bethell (ed.), The Cambridge History of Latin
America, vol. 4: c.1870 to 1930. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 57-81.

- (1998a). Progress, Poverty and Exclusion: An Economic History ofLatin America in the 20th
Century. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press; Inter-American Development Bank.

-(1998b). "The Latin American Economies, 1939-1950," in L. Bethell (ed.), The Cam-
bridge History of Latin America, vol. 6: Latin America since 1930: Economy, Society and
Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

References 285

Thorp, R. (ed.) (2000). An Economic History of Twentieth-Century Latin America, vol. 2:

Latin America in the 1930s: The Role of the Periphery in the World Crisis. Houndmills:

Palgrave, in association with St Antony's College, Oxford.

Thorp, R. and Bertram, G. (1978). Peru 1890-1977: Growth and Policy in an Open

Economy. London: MacMillan.
Tokman, V. E. (2007). Informalidad, inseguridad y cohesion social en America Latina. Serie

Politicas Sociales, 130. Santiago de Chile: ECLAC.

-(2011). "Employment: The Dominance of the Informal Economy," in J. A. Ocampo

and J. Ros (eds), The Oxford Handbook of Latin American Economics. Oxford: Oxford

University Press, 767-89 (ch. 30).
Triffin, R. (1968). Our International Monetary System: Yesterday, Today and Tomorrow.

New York: Random House.

Tussie, D. (2009). "Economic Governance After Neoliberalism," in J, Grugel and

P. Riggirozzi (eds), Governance after Neoliberalism in Latin America. New York: Pal-

grave Macmillan.
United Nations (1955). Foreign Capital in Latin America. New York: United Nations,

Department of Economic and Social Affairs.
Uthoff, A. (2011). "Social Security Reforms in Latin America," in J. A. Ocampo and J, Ros

(eds), The Oxford Handbook of Latin American Economics. Oxford: Oxford University

Press, 863-85 (ch. 34).
Valdes, J. G. (1995). Pinochet's Economists: The Chicago School in Chile. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.
Van Zanden, J, L. (2009). The Long Road to the Industrial Revolution. The European

Economy in a Global Perspective, 1000-1800. Global Economic History Series, l. Leiden

and Boston: Brill. ·

Vazquez Presedo, V. (1988). Estadisticas Hist6ricas. Buenos Aires: Academia Nacional de

Economia.
Webb, R. (2000). "The Influence of International Financial Institutions on lSI," in

E. Cardenas, J, A. Ocampo, and R. Thorp (eds), An Economic History of Twentieth-

Century Latin America, val. 3: Industrialization and the State in Latin America: The

Postwar Years. Houndmills: Palgrave, in association with St Antony's College, Oxford,

98-113 (ch. 4).
Wickizer, V. D. (1942). The World Coffee Economy, with Special References to Control

Schemes. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
Williamson, J, G. (1990). "What Washington Means by Policy Reform," in id. (ed.), Latin

American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? Washington, DC: Institute of Inter-

national Economics.
-(1998). "Growth, Distribution and Demography: Some Lessons from History." Explor-

ations in Economic History, 35/3: 241-71.
-(2002). "Land, Labor, and Globalization in the Third World, 1870-1940." Journal of

Economic History, 62/1: 55-85.
-(2011). Trade and Poverty: When the Third World Fell Behind. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT

Press.
World Bank (1995). Bureaucrats in Business: The Economics and Politics of Government

Ownership. Policy Research Report, No.4. New York: Oxford University Press.

- (1997). The Long March: A Reform Agenda for Latin America and the Caribbean in the

Next Decade, ed. S. J, Burki and G. E. Perry. World Bank Latin American and Caribbean

Viewpoints. Washington, DC: World Bank.
-(2004). Inequality in Latin America: Breaking with History? Washington, DC: World

Bank.
-(2006). Poverty Reduction and Growth: Virtuous and Vicious Circles, ed. G. E. Perry,

0. S. Arias, J, H. Lopez, W. F. Maloney, and L. Serven. Washington, DC: World Bank.

STATISTICAL APPENDIX

Notes to Appendix Tables

Tables A.l. and A.2: GDP and Per Capita GDP

l. We depart from Angus Maddison's data base <http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/> to
obtain GDP and per capita GDP figures for the year 1990 expressed in 1990 inter-
national Gheary-Khamis US Dollars. This benchmark allows us to construct our series
in a way that makes them internationally comparable.

2. 1950-2010. Departing from the 1990 year benchmark, we let the series vary according
the yearly variations of the series provided by ECLAC's Latin America and Caribbean
historical statistical series <http://www.eclac.cl/publicaciones/xml/1/37041/LCG2415e.
pdf>.

3. Before 1950. The available series were spliced at the year 1950. Maddison's series were
used except for the following countries and series:

i. Argentina, 1875-99: Cortes Conde and Harriague (1996).
ii. Brasil, 1870-1912: Goldsmith (1986).
iii. Chile, 1830-1949: Economic History and Cliometrics Lab, Instituto de Economia,

Pontificia Universidad Cat6lica de Chile <http://www.economia.puc.cl/cliolab/
produccion>.
iv. Colombia, 1870-1905 according Kalmanovitz y Lopez Rivera (2009). 1905-25
according to Banco de Ia Republica (1999), El Crecimiento Econ6mico Colombiano
en el siglo XX, Bogota; Fonda de Cultura Econ6mica. 1925-50 according to ECLAC

(1957), Ana/isis y proyecciones del desarrollo econ6mico, Vol III: El desarrollo
econ6mico de Colombia, Mexico: ECLAC.
v. Cuba, 1870-1928: Santamaria, A (2009), Las cuentas nacionales de Cuba, 1690-2009,

Madrid: Instituto de Historia, CSIC.
vi. Peru, 1870-1950: Seminario, B. and Beltran A. "Peru: Crecirniento y Cambia

Estr\lctural en el Siglo XX", El Laberinto del Minotauro, <http://sites.google.
com/site/lbserninario/ >.
vii. Venezuela, 1870-1950: Baptista (2006); however, since this series seems to overesti-
mate long-term growth, it has been adjusted so that the GDP for 1900 is similar to
that of Maddison.

4. Aggregated Latin American GDP and per capita GDP estimates before 1950: As infor-
mation was not available for all the countries for the period before 1950, we had to make
assumptions in order to estimate total GDP and per capita GDP to make the estimates
for some benchmark years: 1870, 1913, 1929 and 1940. Expanding the total GDP and
per capita GDP of the existing sample of countries to the total of the Latin American
population would generate an upward bias, as the relatively high income countries are
overrepresented in the existing estimates. In order to sort this problem, and using the
information for the countries for which we have information, we first estimated the total
GDP and the per capita GDP of each of the three groups of countries of the typology
discussed in Chapter 1 and presented in Table 1.2. These figures were expanded to the
total population of each of the three groups and later on aggregated to generate the total.

Statistical Appendix 287

Table A.3. Latin America: Volatility of GDP, GDP of "Relevant World"
(Trading Partners}, and Terms of Trade, 1870-2008

1. The GDP data of the Latin American countries is taken from Table A.l.
2. The GDP data of the "relevant world" (if not a Latin America countries) was taken from

Maddison.
3. The "relevant world" of each Latin American country is specific to it and was created in

the following way:

i. 1962-2008: a weighted structure of commercial traders of each country was estimated
including only those with exports representing 5% or more of the total, according to
Feenstra and Lipsey (2005) and COMTRADE. The results were used to weight GDP
growth of each trading partner in order to estimate total GDP growth of the relevant
world.

ii. For the period before 1962, the same procedure was applied to the data kindly
provided by Antonio Tena, resulting from his project "Nuevas Interpretaciones
sabre Ia Integraci6n Econ6mica de las Periferias Europeas y Latinoamericanas
entre 1850 y 1950".

4. The terms of trade series were constructed on the basis of:

i. Up to 1940: Williamson (2011).
ii. After 1940, ECLAC and MOxLAD.

Table A.l. Latin America: GDP (in millions of 1990 international Geary-Khamis dollars)

Year Argentina Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Costa Rica Cuba Ecuador El Salvador Guatemala Honduras Mexico Nicaragua Panama Paraguay Peru Dominican Republic Uruguay Venezuela Total

1870 2,673 6,935 2,554 1,740 1,418 5,906 2,193 738 942 29,103.42
1871 7,063 2,561 1,778 1,484 2,328 761 966
1872 3,583 7,417 2,754 1,817 11,272 2,388 945 991
1873 3,660 7,321 2,937 1,857 2,198 2,398 965 1,017
1874 4,035 7,578 2,816 1,898 13,626 2,274 884 1,Q43
1875 3,839 7,852 3,049 1,940 1,650 592 2,130 765 1,078
1876 4,005 7,691 3,017 1,983 2,435 619 17,664 2,112 854 1,115
1877 3,925 7,627 2,921 2,026 2,277 647 19,167 2,123 888 1,154
1878 3,988 8,141 3,098 2,071 3,053 677 17,812 2,134 969 1,193
1879 5,023 8,367 3,569 2,116 3,574 708 19,807 1,672 865 1,234
1880 5,629 8,141 4,011 2,163 4,156 739 20,152 1,542 953 1,312
1881 6,030 8,351 4,152 2,210 3,715 773 22,247 1,553 919 1,394
1882 7,068 8,705 4,498 2,259 22,000 1,566 1,030 1,482
1883 7,098 8,624 4,525 2,309 1,658 1,235 1,575
1884 7,580 9,396 4,565 2,360 1,739 1,245 1,674
1885 8,796 8,882 4,429 2,411 1,750 1,430 1,718
1886 9,650 9,075 4,617 2,464 1,718 1,511 1,762
1887 8,852 8,930 4,940 2,494 1,730 1,365 1,808
1888 8,379 8,753 4,744 2,524 1,777 1,703 1,855
1889 10,004 8,994 4,867 2,554 1,814 1,573 1,904
1890 10,601 10,056 5,220 2,585 1,824 1,454 1,922
1891 12,217 10,909 5,646 2,616 1,837 1,596 1,941
1892 13,548 9,702 5,533 2,647 1,799 1,646 1,961
1893 14,983 8,463 5,808 2,679 1,802 1,799 1,980
1894 12,158 8,656 5,713 2,711 1,760 2,019 1,999
1895 13,183 10,523 6,113 2,744 1,775 2,007 2,011
1896 15,507 9,750 6,148 2,777 1,904 2,127 2,022
1897 13,682 9,847 6,012 2,810 2,081 2,065 2,034
1898 14,851 10,330 6,740 2,844 2,216 1,918 2,045
1899 14,543 10,378 6,783 2,878 2,339 1,984 2,057
1900 16,634 10,249 6,609 2,912 2,463 2,003 2,079
1901 18,417 11,456 6,774 2,947 2,643 2,050 2,031
1902 10,846 12,260 7,070 2,983 2,788 2,399 2,194
1903 21,892 12,341 6,673 3,019 2,977 2,480 2,356
1904 12,373 7,219 3,055 3,077 2,545 2,285
1905 12,646 7,212 3,091 3,303 2,288 2,242
1906 13,226 7,776 3,179 3,567 2,522 2,078

1907 22,353 15,060 8,187 3,389 735 3,362 808 1,279 2,032 959 23,281 822 1,837 3,790 2,792 2,064 117,030.86
1908 24,536 13,564 9,056 3,578 720 3,812 853 1,283 2,231 970 23,256 853 1,739 3,862 3,060 2,191 194,855.18
1909 25,766 14,996 9,102 3,767 784 4,262 901 1,359 2,106 1,055 23,946 781 1,767 3,927 3,099 2,253 242,637.08
1910 27,641 16,090 10,131 3,981 724 4,024 951 1,417 2,316 1,048 24,144 836 1,871 3,995 3,345 2,311
1911 28,133 16,154 9,857 4,178 829 4,015 1,004 1,515 2,504 979 24,316 886 1,910 4,081 3,245 2,454
1912 30,439 17,860 10,248 4,383 826 4,394 1,060 1,411 2,456 1,182 24,464 978 1,951 4,224 3,960 2,522
1913 30,747 18,149 10,436 4,574 913 5,215 1,121 1,668 2,480 1,193 24,636 850 4,365 3,845 2,892
1914 27,549 17,753 8,819 4,748 829 4,853 1,170 1,466 2,643 1,310 24,801 854 4,339 3,203 2,511
1915 27,703 18,549 8,535 4,968 872 5,594 1,223 1,719 2,702 1,473 24,968 1,082 4,713 3,038 2,571
1916 26,903 19,090 10,463 5,223 835 6,636 1,267 1,722 3,016 1,459 25,135 1,209 5,201 3,141 2,409
1917 24,720 20,410 10,688 5,438 876 4,924 1,311 1,765 3,145 1,554 25,304 977 5,393 3,465 2,792
1918 29,271 19,995 10,824 5,740 865 4,474 1,358 1,582 2,933 1,587 25,474 914 5,425 3,672 2,757
1919 30,347 22,634 9,286 6,217 796 4,906 1,419 1,419 2,567 1,422 25,645 823 5,606 4,149 2,557
1920 32,561 24,866 10,490 6,642 948 5,956 1,483 1,611 2,593 1,334 25,817 1,035 5,662 3,618 3,050
1921 33,391 25,385 9,092 7,024 836 5,665 1,536 1,664 2,933 1,292 25,990 940 5,896 3,806 3,153
1922 36,035 27,134 9,425 7,500 905 5,718 1,590 1,832 3,390 1,235 26,606 955 6,404 4,353 3,218
1923 40,032 28,692 11,352 7,978 966 7,438 1,646 1,791 4,657 1,257 27,518 760 6,845 4,583 3,688
1924 43,137 28,673 12,208 8,431 1,126 7,059 1,704 1,961 4,567 1,201 27,075 824 7,490 5,022 4,243
1925 42,953 28,788 12,739 8,886 1,193 6,274 1,764 1,822 4,693 1,271 28,750 852 7,688 4,826 5,446
1926 45,013 29,404 11,678 9,735 1,228 5,718 1,821 1,955 5,282 1,307 30,475 1,059 8,469 5,268 6,542
1927 48,211 31,539 11,466 10,612 1,178 6,150 1,916 2,124 6,034 1,396 29,144 1,157 8,618 6,026 7,289
1928 51,224 35,172 14,046 11,391 1,319 6,618 2,023 2,078 6,357 1,393 29,317 1,266 9,174 6,345 8,107
1929 53,560 35,250 14,780 11,801 1,182 6,274 2,135 2,258 6,440 1,273 28,183 1,219 10,133 6,398 9,131
1930 51,347 33,151 12,414 11,699 1,180 5,910 2,216 2,448 4,293 1,275 26,410 1,337 8,972 7,271 9,232
1931 47,780 32,410 9,780 11,513 1,069 4,965 2,230 2,322 4,162 1,305 27,296 1,324 8,246 6,014 7,411
1932 46,212 33,539 8,264 12,276 3,984 2,244 23,207 7,930 5,583 7,051
1933 48,364 36,153 10,183 12,966 4,310 2,294 25,843 8,822 4,883 7,662
1934 52,208 39,178 12,293 13,782 5,062 2,344 27,592 10,016 5,814 8,121
1935 54,514 40,250 13,001 14,119 5,922 2,404 29,637 10,955 6,156 8,651
1936 54,883 44,114 13,640 14,866 6,903 2,486 32,002 11,481 6,448 9,439
1937 58,880 45,557 15,508 15,097 7,932 2,566 33,062 11,637 6,564 10,755
1938 59,126 47,461 15,687 16,080 6,151 2,657 33,603 11,820 7,082 11,549
1939 61,370 47,932 16,016 17,066 6,492 2,747 35,402 11,884 7,083 12,166
1940 62,385 48,408 16,658 17,436 5,643 2,928 35,895 12,114 7,099 11,614
1941 65,582 51,799 16,469 17,728 7,581 2,943 38,826 12,126 7,221 ll,346
1942 66,351 49,880 17,234 17,764 6,358 3,067 41,585 11,848 6,621 9,854
1943 65,828 56,826 17,726 17,837 7,Q48 3,455 43,137 12,035 6,679 10,684
1944 73,300 58,941 18,060 19,Q43 8,090 3,501 46,660 13,068 7,513 13,089

(continued)


Click to View FlipBook Version